The Foundations of the Separation of Powers in Companies

Slide Note
Embed
Share

The separation of powers in companies is based on the dualism of organs: the Board and General Meeting. The actual situation in companies diverges between large public companies with autonomous management and smaller private companies with owner-operators. The search for the foundations of the separation of powers leads back to the origins of company law, including the historical development of joint enterprises and chartered companies. The success of chartered companies and their imitators, although with downsides, has proven to be a successful model in company governance.


Uploaded on Sep 28, 2024 | 0 Views


Download Presentation

Please find below an Image/Link to download the presentation.

The content on the website is provided AS IS for your information and personal use only. It may not be sold, licensed, or shared on other websites without obtaining consent from the author. Download presentation by click this link. If you encounter any issues during the download, it is possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Foundations of the Separation of Powers in Companies - a Comparative Perspective PD Dr. Alexander Schall, M.Jur. (Oxon)

  2. The separation of powers (SOP) in companies SOP in companies is based on dualism of organs: Board (one-tier or two-tier) General Meeting Despite universality of SOP, actual situation in companies diverges Large (listed) public companies: Autonomous management, investors reduced to control real separation of ownership and control Small private companies: shareholders as owner-operators only formal separation of ownership and control Search for foundations of SOP leads to origins of company law

  3. The origins of company law Two basic role models for joint enterprises: Partners on equal footing Brain meets capital Reflected for centuries in corresponding legal forms: Partnership Roman societas Italian compagnia Limited partnership Roman societas publicanorum (eg tax collecting companies) and peculium (kind of business trust for business of slaves or sons ) 1408: Florentine accomandita , derived from maritime trade ( commenda ) Cf. further the English trust

  4. The third way: Chartered companies facilitate entrepreneur-agents Corporate personality originates in the domain of public/church bodies (separation of office and office-holder). It is granted in particular by royal charters Royal charters also confer monopolies on trading companies , organised as guilds, with the members trading on own account Trading on joint account and under the name of the company begins with the East India companies in the Netherlands and in England (need to limit risks of long distance trade). Development of chartered companies , administered by governors , as investment vehicle soliciting private investment (usually to fulfil public functions, like did the Roman societas publicanorum) Result: Entrepreneurial agents enjoying wide autonomy in day-to-day running of the business because original principal (crown) often passive whereas investors barred from taking over complete control (one cannot buy state power )

  5. The success of the chartered companies and their imitators Concept of chartered companies, in particular colonial companies, proves successful in principle Thomas Smythe and the first clash of board and investors in the East India Company The concept of chartered companies as investment vehicle spreads over Europe (e.g. France, Roman Empire) Attempts to mimic structure by contractual imitations (to avoid discretion of grants by the crown) Continent: limited partnership England: deed of settlement companies (combined trust/partnership) Downsides of contractual approach No escape of personal liability for managers/trustees No easy way to get rid of managers (partners!)

  6. The Death of the King Demise of chartered companies from Mid of 18th century on First corporate scandals (South Sea Bubble) American and French Revolution Chartered companies face hard times on both sides of Atlantic Concession system replaces charter system for stock corporations (in France, Germany and the US) alternative of limited partnership with tradable shares remains attractive to avoid state control Finally, the registration system prevails (starting 1844 in the UK) the modern company is born

  7. The decline of SOP rise of contract (I) Code de Commerce (1807) recognises soci t anonyme as third form next to partnership ( en nom collectif ) and limited partnership (en commandite ) Common basis: contract of shareholders for joint purpose Features: Legal personality ( personne morale ) Limited Liability of board and shareholders Supremacy of general meeting, board merely delegates Concession allows state control (step back from active governance) Coins German stock corporations Two investment vehicles co-exist: Stock corporation (with shareholder supremacy) Limited partnership on stocks (with management supremacy due to personal liability)

  8. The decline of SOP - rise of contract (II) UK: Joint Stock Corporations Act 1844: Codified company (but not partnership/limited partnership) no common legal basis for societies Features: Separate legal personality Limited liability only of board shareholders as contributories (till 1855) Supremacy of general meeting (e.g. right to interfere with management) US: Company as contract (Dartmouth College v. Woodward, 1819 but see Dodge v. Woolsey, 1855: shareholders cannot overrule rights vested by Charter Contractual freedom promoted by deregulation due to regulatory competition by end of 19th century

  9. The decline of SOP - emergence of private companies Contractual freedom allows adaption of company model to smaller businesses Few shareholders actually able to run company, e.g. via instructions or holding directorships Owner-operator structures become common From end of 19th century, company model extended to smaller enterprises Germany: GmbHG 1892 comes to France via Alsace-Lorraine UK: Salomon Case, 1907 Act US: Close corporations SOP undermined by reunion of management and ownership

  10. The restoration of SOP During first half of 20th century, SOP is restored in large companies Mandatory and exclusive board competence to manage company France: Arr t Motte (1946) US: Mason v Curtis (1918) Germany: Aktiengesetz 1937 See also UK: Automatic self-cleansing v Cunnighame (1906) - board competence as general rule, but subject to articles Probably because capital market enforced SOP sufficently Background: board supremacy corresponds actual situation, legal choice has no benefit but leads to uncertainty (investors) New problems arise: material transactions by board

  11. Some observations The legal personality of the company is still a mystery. This becomes immediately obvious beyond the black letter law: Long line of logical inconsistencies and ill-fitting analogies, e.g. company as contract/partnership/trust; share as property Mandatory SOP inconsistent with contractual basis of company and subordinated role of agents Shareholders as supreme body of company, board as mere delegate But: comprehensible from the privilege perspective (Dodge v. Woolsey) Why should UK shareholders still dominate company after abolition of their liability? Why were operators in private companies allowed to simply abolish SOP without loosing benefits of limited liability? Constant difficulty to explain what happened to the King s governor after the King s death reign of shareholder remains restricted Company appears to be a privilege granted by the state, not a right to be recognised by the state (contrast freedom of contract)

  12. Conclusions: nature of company Company is not a mere contract (or nexus of contracts), because neither separate legal personality and asset partitioning (entity shielding) nor limited liability (owner shielding) can be effected by contract Privity of contract no binding of third parties (principle of given, natural law) State grant necessary Consequence: Wide state discretion for shaping corporate governance structure (mandatory law, shareholder rule, board structure, permissible objects, stakeholder approach)

  13. Conclusions: SOP (I) After decades of criticism (principal-agent-debate), the demand for the entrepreneur-agent displayed by the course of history underpins the virtues of SOP: Freed from pressure by personal liability or pressing investors, agents are like judges and civil servants free to act for what they consider best for the company (positive attitude to freedom). Well-working SOP prevents abuses of all kind ( checks and balances ) and helps justifying the privilege of legal personality and limited liability. The latter point is demonstrated by the fact that we discuss shadow director concepts, fiduciary duties of shareholders, minority oppression remedies, veil-piercing etc. as soon as shareholders overstep SOP by assuming managerial functions.

  14. Conclusions: SOP (II) Shareholder supremacy is new threat to the entrepreneur-agent Permanent performance pressure from the capital markets reduces managerial freedom Shareholder value serves selfishness of the capital that may violate the common purpose of the company just as well as selfishness on the part of the agents Concentration on capital interests is both one-sided (company as privilege at expense of third parties) and shortsighted (capital is not loyal). Management fantasy diverts from business strategies to financial doping (e.g. leverage)

  15. Conclusions SOP (III) Law has to crown a new king, e.g. by: Legal ban on pure shareholder value: Mandatory stakeholderism Enlightened shareholder (sustainability) Taking legal persons seriously: The company has to be conducted as a good merchant (honesty, prudence, respect). It is not identical All players bound to common corporate purpose by fiduciary duties (prohibits detrimental activity to shareholders - but: shareholder passivity is allowed) Taming capital (markets) via unlimited liability for key financial institutions shareholders closer to risk, thus cheapest cost avoider

Related


More Related Content