Structural Identification in Vector Autoregressions

Structural identification of vector
autoregressions
Tony Yates
Lectures to MSc Time Series
students, Bristol, Spring 2014
Overview
The algebra of the identification problem in
VARs.
Cholesky-factoring;  timing restrictions.
Long run impact restrictions.
(Max share restrictions).
Sign restrictions.
Identification through heteroskedasticity.
Some useful sources
Luktepohl, Hamilton.
Kilian survey.
Wouter den Haan lecture notes
Karl Whelan lecture notes
Many more!
Why bother with structural
identification
Empirical form of business cycle accounting,
which is important for informing policy.  Eg if RBC
claim that tech shocks dominant true, maybe no
need for stabilisation policy?
Not needed for forecasting.
Needed for estimation of our economic models,
eg impulse response function matching.
Hence needed to understand appropriate policy
design.  Eg identify a policy shock.
Lucas(1980) on why identifying shocks
is important
Methods and problems in business cycle theory, JMCB
Reduced form vs structural model for Y
We are estimating this VAR(p), in the 
vector
 Y....
..in order to learn about this structural
model, with different coefficients, and
driven by structural shocks
Structural shocks mutually
uncorrelated, and normalised so that
vcov matrix is identity=dimension of Y
Structural vs reduced form VARs
Once we have estimated the reduced form VAR for Y, if only we knew the B_0, we
could recover the sructural shocks, and ALL the coefficients of the structrual
model.
If only!!
Structural identification is about trying to find B_0.
Long and controversial story.
We will tell it chronologically.
Idealised factorisation of the reduced
form vcov matrix
LHS known;  RHS elements unknown.  System of nonlinear equations.
Need to restrict B_0 so that have same number of unknowns as
equations.
Sigma_e is symmetric, as it’s a vcov matrix, hence has K(K+1)/2
independent elements only.
B_0 not necessarily symmetric
Referred to as ‘order condition’ for identification.
Simple illustration of the identification
problem in 2 dimensions
We estimate this 2 variable reduced
form VAR(1) to learn about this 2
variable structural VAR.
Here we invert the coefficient matrix B0 so that the structural VAR has
the same form as the reduced form VAR.
Which allows us to see relation between rf and structural errors….
Identification problem in 2
dimensions, ctd…
First line:  we compute the vcov matrix of reduced form errors which
we see has only 3 separate elements.
Second line:  we note that this is equal to inv(B0)*inv(B0)’.
Problem:  this is a 2*2 with 4 independent unknown elements.
We have only 3 knowns to find these 4 unknowns.
This is the identification problem in VARs/SVARs.
Cholesky identification
P is lower triangular
Used eg to identify a monetary policy shock
Assumes strict causal chain in the VAR
GDP and inflation don’t react within period to
a monetary policy shock.
For those studying DSGE models.
Third equation looks like a central bank reaction function.
But it isn’t!  Coefficients of the central bank reaction function will show up in all
of the VARs reduced form equations.
See, eg, Canova comment on Benati/Surico paper.
Recovering the monetary policy shock
and structural coefficients with
Cholesky identification
Finishing the 3d monetary policy shock
Our expression for the mon
pol shock u_it was in terms
of some unknowns.
Here we can get rid of one of
them, u_xt.
Here we get rid of the
second, u_pit, also using
expression for u_xt
And we are done.  u_it now
entirely in terms of knowns.
Impulse responses to the structural
shocks
We can use the reduced form VAR estimates to compute the response to
structural shocks.
Our structural shocks are functions of the reduced form shocks, a function
of our assumed value for B_0.
So we then feed these through the reduced form VAR in the normal way,
taking successively higher and higher powers of the A matrix.
Problems with recursive structure
implied by Cholesky identification
Is it economically plausible?  Quarterly data.
Does output or inflation really not respond to
interest rates within the quarter?
Assumed causal ordering means we can’t use
the VAR to find out about causality.
Common practice to check for robustness to
alternative causal orderings, but this is rarely
done comprehensively;  and [so Kilian says] is
nonsensical!
Recap on causal assumptions in
Cholesky identification of mon pol
shock
Neither e_x nor e_pi are functions
of the structural shock u_it.
Implies output gap and inflation
do not respond [within the
period] to a monetary policy
shock.
Is this really plausible?
Remember the NK DSGE model.
If we trace the timing of the effects of the monetary policy shock, we can
see that it affects inflation and the output gap straight away.
Of course, the NK model could be a load of nonsense!
More problems with recursive
identification.
Sims and the ‘price puzzle’.
Would find that recursively identified, contract
mon pol shock leads to 
increase
 in prices,
contrary to theory.
Concluded that had omitted variable cb
responding to, eg commodity prices.
CP up means prices up, despite central bank
rate increase.
Recursive ID problems:  omitted
variables
Omitted variable bias leads us to enlarge the
VAR.
But there is a cost:  imprecision in the
coefficients.  And the search for more
restrictions.
Solutions:  Bayesian shrinkage and factor
modelling to reduce dimensionality.
In time we will cover both of these.
What are these mp shocks anyway?
Why would policymakers induce shocks?
Are they really conducting experiments for their own
edification [a control literature involving Sargent,
Cogley shows there is a benefit].  Alan Blinder says not.
Shocks are just misspecifications by econometrician
Shocks are policymakers’ real time measurement
error?
Shocks are policymakers’ [or our] model mis-
specification
Same goes, of course, for fiscal policy shocks.
Alternative, less intensive measures of
identifying (eg) mp shocks
Romer and Romer (1989) 
narrative measures
of monetary policy (and fiscal policy) shocks.
Rudebusch (1998)
:  gap between actual Fed
Funds Rate and expectations implied by Fed
Funds futures.
Romer and Romer’s narrative shock
definition
Problem:  they are including movements in rates prompted by concerns about inflation.
So if we think i=a*pi+b*y+shock, they are not identifying m p shocks
Romer and Romer(1989), quoting
Friedman and Schwartz (1964)
Rudebusch, and Sims on Rudebusch
Rudebusch:  FFFs produce better forecasts
than VARs.  His surprise a better measure of
policy ‘shocks’.
Sims (1996)
: 1.  False premise.  FFR shocks
confound surprises due to non policy shocks
with those due to shocks.  2.  Not true that if
shock measures badly correlated, estimated
effects are very different.
Famous applications
Rotemburg and Woodford (1998).
Early application.  Estimated DSGE model by fitting
IRFs of monetary policy shock using MDE.
Later pointed out that in DSGE model
EVERYTHING responds within the period to
monetary policy.
Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (2005)
Same exercise.  But DSGE model 
is
 consistent with
timing assumption.
Minimum distance estimation
DSGE model is defined by a vector of parameters, PHI.
We take as our PHI_hat the value of these parameters that makes
the impulse response in the DSGE model as close as possible to
the identified, estimated IRF in the VAR.
Some costs and benefits wrt eg MLE estimation of DSGE model.
Cost:  partial information, means bad identification.
Benefit:  MLE only consistent if model well-specified.
Identification using long run
restrictions
Attractive because much agreement on
certain long run restrictions.  So these are
‘credible’ in Sims language.  At least among
members of the RBC/DSGE cult [like me]!
Famous early applications are 
Blanchard and
Quah (1989)
, and 
Gali (1999).  
More later.
Technique sparked famous arguments
between 
Chari 
et al
 
and VAR proponents,
notably Christiano and coauthors.
Egs of restrictions uncontroversial, at
least in DSGE/RBC-land
Nominal shocks should have no long run
impact on real variables.
Corrollary:  only real shocks should have a
long run impact on real variables.
Real shocks like technology should be neutral
on inflation in the long run.
Only inflation regime changes should affect
inflation in the long run.
Deriving long run restrictions for an
SVAR
Reduced form VAR(1) with an expression in terms of
structural shocks and the unkown structural impact
matrix substiuted in place of the RF shock
This is how we would compute the IRF to the
structural shock, if only we knew the structural
impat matrix....
You can see this defines an infinite sequence.  Effect
on level of something=0, implies sum of effects on
difference=0.
Deriving long run restrictions
Factor the long run IRF in terms of
something you might recognise from high
school as the expression for an infinite
geometric series, or its matrix equivalent.
Some algebra and we spot that DD’
involves something we can estimate
from the data, the vcov of the RF
residuals!
Long run restrictions and the Cholesky
factor, again
 
DD’
 which we know to be related
to the magic B0 which we are
trying to find…
…we also know to be related
entirely to things we do know.
Gali’s (AER, 1999) search for
technology shocks
Only the tech shock (which we say comes first,
has a long run effect on the first variable, (the
change in) output per hour
Celebrated applications of LR
restrictions
Blanchard-Quah.   Tech shock is the only thing to affect
output in the long run.  Q:   how important are tech
shocks in driving the business cycle?
Gali (1999).  Tech shock is only thing driving labour
productivity.  Appears to cause hours to fall, not rise.
Consistent with sticky price model, not RBC models.
Hours tend to comove positively with business cycle.
Suggests tech shocks not dominant driver of business
cycle.
Christiano-Eichenbaum-Vigfussen ()
.  Reexamination of
Gali.  Conclusion depends on definition of hours
worked used in VAR
Identification of VARs using sign
restrictions
Cholesky factorisation of rf varcov can be expanded with product of any
orthonormal matrix
So, parameterising with the angle theta, we choose all those that satisfy certain
sign restrictions
Sign is the ‘signum’ function;  S is a selector matrix with ones for restricted
elements, 0s otherwise.  C is our givens matrix.  A is our estimated rf impact matrix.
Signum function and the selector
matrix
An example of what the signum
function does to a matrix.
Turns things into 0s, 1s or -1s.
Just a way to record in an
algorithm whether things are
positive, negative or zero.
Could do it differently, with
more if, then else statements.
An example of doing element by element multiplication with a
selector matrix.
Verbal description of sign restrictions
Take cholesky factor of vcov matrix 
P
Multiply by some Givens, 
C(theta)
Check signs of elements of interest.
If they agree with your restrictions, store and
keep.
If not, move on.
At the end, plot ALL the IRFs, and or
summarise them somehow.
 
i=cb rate, pi=inflation, x=output,
ur=unemployment rate
Mp shock in first column:  contraction
raises rate, lowers pi, lowers output,
lowers unemployment.
Tech shock in second column:  reduction
has ambiguous effect on i, increases pi,
lowers output, ambiguous effect on ue
Demand shock in third column:  cb raises
rates to fight it, inflation and output
increase anyway, ue falls.
Fourth shock unidentified.  A dustbin
containing many things we don’t need to
worry about.
Alternative way to do sign restrictions
using the QR decomposition
Any square matrix can be decomposed into a product of an orthonormal
matrix and something else.
Matlab will calculate this for you in a flash.
Note equivalence which seems not to be widely understood.  Derives from
fact that all orthonormal matrices can be shown to be product of Givens
matrices.
Personal preference:  use Givens method.  Systematic way to explore the
space.
Random number generators for step 1 in computers are not random, they are
pseudo random.  Don’t know if this matters much.
Sign restrictions at different or
multiple horizons
Choose h the horizon, then
keep IRF if it satisifies this
condition
For multiple horizons, keep if the condition above applied for
multiple horizons holds!
Warning:  spanning the entire space of
possible impulse responses
A givens indexed by one angle only not
enough to guarantee to find all possible IRFs
that satisfy the sign restriction, except in the
2  variable case [eg n=2, 2*(1)/2=1]
More generally, we need to search across
orthonormal matrices formed by products of
Givens matrices.
Reporting distributions from sign
restrictions
Sign restrictions generate arbitrary numbers of impulse response functions.
How to report them?  Can just plot the whole damned lot.
People used to report moments at each 
h
 eg the median.
Fry and Pagan 
suggested above.  Find the single SVAR corresponding to single
angle that is closest to this median.
Sign restrictions:  examples
Giraitis, Kapetanios, Yates.
Actually a TVP study, but don’t worry about
that until later on in the lecture series.
Sign restrictions to identify various shocks.
Studies time variation in the IRFs.
Sign restrictions in Giraitis, Kapetanios,
Yates
 
 
Identification using Mountford and
Uhlig’s penalty method
w_h are weights;  V records not just signs, but magnitudes.
Why would you do this?  Isn’t it just assuming the answer?
Well, one motivation is to use one implication of the model to test
another, that you don’t impose.
Another is that some rotations may satisfy the sign restriction literally,
but you want the IRF not just to clear the zero line by a tiny amount.
Using the ‘max share’ criterion in a
VAR to identify news shocks
Barsky-Sims (2010):
  identified news shocks for
technology.
Long history of identifying technology shocks,
measuring impact, quantifying contribution to
business cycles
RE assumption suggests agents may also react to
news about future events.
Failure to account for this may mislead us in
properly measuring and quantifying effects of
technology shocks.
Other work on news shocks
Beaudry-Portier
:  news shocks in VARs:  news
causes hours to 
increase
.
Jaimovich and Rebello
:  news shocks in RBC
model, neutralising the wealth effect so that
hours don’t fall.
Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2012
):  multiple news
shocks in large RBC style model
Christiano, Motto, Rostagno 
and Pinter,
Theodoridis and Yates:  
risk
 news shocks in DSGE
model and VAR respectively
News shocks:  algebra
Note annoying change of notation;  matches Barsky-Sims.  Sorry.  Good for the
soul though.
This slide is about writing down the expression for the forecast error up to
horizon h.
News shocks identification, ctd...
The share of the FEV up to
horizon h, of variable i,
accounted for by shock j...
Example news process for tfp.
Could be more general than this.
In an ideal setting, share of current and news shock to tfp
that accounts for tfp should be 1.  tfp is exogenous after
all!
News shocks:  the max share criterion
By choice of the K.(K-1)/2 vector of angles
w, maximise the share of tfp forecast
error variance up to horizon h, accounted
for by the news shock to tfp, subject to
the restriction that the news shock is
orthogonal to tfp today.  [if it weren’t, it
wouldn’t be news, it would be a contemp.
Shock to tfp]
In Pinter, Theodoridis and Yates, in our
search for ‘risk news’ shocks, we impose
a sign restrictions condition too.
Comments on news shock ID
Method proposed originally as an alternative
to LR restrictions that does not depend on
uncovering zero frequency events in finite
samples:  see work by 
Faust
 and Diebold 
et al
.
Note practical contradiction.  Proxy for shock
is supposed to be exogenous, but is included
as an endogenous variable.
Monte carlo tests in economic laboratory
show that it works in ‘theory’.
Application : ‘risk news shock’ in
Pinter, Theodoridis and Yates
Looks for the same shock as in 
CMR(2013), AER
.
Risk shocks are fluctuations in the variance of
idiosyncratic returns to entrepreneurs.
Literally, in CMR, these guys build capital goods
from capital inputs, selling them to sticky-price
producers.
They borrow from banks at a spread related to
their cross-sectional risk.
Higher risk means more defaults, means bigger
spread to compensate.
Pinter, Theodoridis, Yates
VAR study allows us to drop lots of
contestable assumptions in the full
information estimation of CMR’s DSGE model.
Cost:  we have to assume we can observe risk.
Do this using the VIX, and using cross section
of stock returns computed from a US panel.
Risk proxies
‘F’: Sign and zero restrictions in the
VAR
IRF to a risk news shock:  VIX vs CSR
FEVD contributions (VIX)
Headlines from application
PTY get a much smaller contribution of the
risk and risk news shocks to the business cycle
than CMR.  20% contribution in total,
compared to 60% in CMR.
Rigobon:  identification through
heteroskedasticity
If you can persuasively argue there was a
change in the structural shock variances
And at the same time the VARs coefficients
were constant
Then you can use the change to generate
more equations to find your unknowns and
get identification.
In the limit, this is like event study analysis.
 
Similar variance of demand and supply shocks generates cloud of dots, unable
to see shape of either curve of course.
 
Increase in variance of supply shocks starts to trace out shape of demand
curve helping us to ‘identify’ demand coefficients.
In the limit : event study;  no demand shocks at all.
The identification problem:  Rigobon’s
simple demand-supply example
A simultaneous demand and supply system.
All we observe is time series on prices P and
quantities Q
We try to estimate four unknowns, the two slopes,
and the two shock variances
However all we can estimate consistently is the reduced form vcov matrix.
Its symmetry means we only have 3 different elements, so this is 3 equations
in 4 unknowns.
Rigobon’s heteroskedasticity solution
to the identification problem
There are TWO values for s, so we have TWO reduced form vcov
matrices.
This means two lots of 3 equations=6.
Slope coefficients are unchanged, so they provide 2 unknowns as
before.
Structural variances change, so there are now double 2=4
unknowns.
Making 6 equations in 6 unknowns.
Luktepohl has applied this to VARs.
Slide Note
Embed
Share

Explore the algebra of identification problems in VARs, including Cholesky factorization, timing restrictions, long-run impact restrictions, sign restrictions, and identification through heteroskedasticity. Discover why structural identification is crucial for policy design, economic modeling, and understanding shocks in business cycle theory. Learn about the difference between reduced form and structural models in VARs and the challenges in recovering structural shocks and coefficients. Gain insights into the ideal factorization of the reduced form vcov matrix in structural identification.

  • VARs
  • Structural Identification
  • Vector Autoregressions
  • Policy Design
  • Business Cycle Theory

Uploaded on Sep 30, 2024 | 0 Views


Download Presentation

Please find below an Image/Link to download the presentation.

The content on the website is provided AS IS for your information and personal use only. It may not be sold, licensed, or shared on other websites without obtaining consent from the author. Download presentation by click this link. If you encounter any issues during the download, it is possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Structural identification of vector autoregressions Tony Yates Lectures to MSc Time Series students, Bristol, Spring 2014

  2. Overview The algebra of the identification problem in VARs. Cholesky-factoring; timing restrictions. Long run impact restrictions. (Max share restrictions). Sign restrictions. Identification through heteroskedasticity.

  3. Some useful sources Luktepohl, Hamilton. Kilian survey. Wouter den Haan lecture notes Karl Whelan lecture notes Many more!

  4. Why bother with structural identification Empirical form of business cycle accounting, which is important for informing policy. Eg if RBC claim that tech shocks dominant true, maybe no need for stabilisation policy? Not needed for forecasting. Needed for estimation of our economic models, eg impulse response function matching. Hence needed to understand appropriate policy design. Eg identify a policy shock.

  5. Lucas(1980) on why identifying shocks is important Methods and problems in business cycle theory, JMCB

  6. Reduced form vs structural model for Y We are estimating this VAR(p), in the vector Y.... Yt A1Yt 1 A2Yt 2 A3Yt 3 ...ApYt p et B0Yt B1Yt 1 ...BpYt p ut I B L Yt ut ..in order to learn about this structural model, with different coefficients, and driven by structural shocks Structural shocks mutually uncorrelated, and normalised so that vcov matrix is identity=dimension of Y u IK E utut

  7. Structural vs reduced form VARs 1B0Yt B0 Yt B0 Ai B0 1B1Yt 1 ...B0 1B1Yt 1 ...B0 1Bi,et B0 1BpYt p B0 1BpYt p B0 1ut 1ut B0 1ut Once we have estimated the reduced form VAR for Y, if only we knew the B_0, we could recover the sructural shocks, and ALL the coefficients of the structrual model. If only!! Structural identification is about trying to find B_0. Long and controversial story. We will tell it chronologically.

  8. Idealised factorisation of the reduced form vcov matrix 1E utut 1 uB0 1 B0 1 B0 e B0 e B0 1B0 1 LHS known; RHS elements unknown. System of nonlinear equations. Need to restrict B_0 so that have same number of unknowns as equations. Sigma_e is symmetric, as it s a vcov matrix, hence has K(K+1)/2 independent elements only. B_0 not necessarily symmetric Referred to as order condition for identification.

  9. Simple illustration of the identification problem in 2 dimensions We estimate this 2 variable reduced form VAR(1) to learn about this 2 variable structural VAR. y1 y2 e1 e2 Yt AYt 1 t t b0,11 b0,12 b0,21 b0,22 b1,11 b1,12 b1,21 b1,22 y1 y2 y1 y2 u1 u2 t 1 t t 1 1 b1,11 b1,12 b1,21 b1,22 b1,11 b1,12 b1,21 b1,22 b1,11 b1,12 b1,21 b1,22 y1 y2 y1 y2 u1 u2 t 1 t t Here we invert the coefficient matrix B0 so that the structural VAR has the same form as the reduced form VAR. Which allows us to see relation between rf and structural errors .

  10. Identification problem in 2 dimensions, ctd e1 e2 e1 e2 e,11 e,21 e,21 e,22 e E 1 1 2 2 b1,11 b1,21 b1,21 b1,22 b1,11 b1,12 b1,21 b1,22 b1,11 b1,12 b1,21 b1,22 2 2 First line: we compute the vcov matrix of reduced form errors which we see has only 3 separate elements. Second line: we note that this is equal to inv(B0)*inv(B0) . Problem: this is a 2*2 with 4 independent unknown elements. We have only 3 knowns to find these 4 unknowns. This is the identification problem in VARs/SVARs.

  11. Cholesky identification P is lower triangular Used eg to identify a monetary policy shock Assumes strict causal chain in the VAR GDP and inflation don t react within period to a monetary policy shock. e PP ,P chol e P B0 1 0 0 0 0 xt t it p11 p21 p22 p31 p32 p33 p11 p21 p22 p31 p32 p33 ux u ui B1Yt 1 ... Yt 0 0 t For those studying DSGE models. Third equation looks like a central bank reaction function. But it isn t! Coefficients of the central bank reaction function will show up in all of the VARs reduced form equations. See, eg, Canova comment on Benati/Surico paper.

  12. Recovering the monetary policy shock and structural coefficients with Cholesky identification 0 0 ex e ei p11 p21 p22 p31 p32 p33 ux u ui 0 t t eit p31uxt p32u t p33uit eit p31uxt p32u t p33 uit 1Bi Ai B0 1 0 0 p11 p21 p22 p31 p32 p33 B1 A1 0

  13. Finishing the 3d monetary policy shock eit p31uxt p32u t p33 Our expression for the mon pol shock u_it was in terms of some unknowns. uit ext p11uxt uxt ext/p11 Here we can get rid of one of them, u_xt. e t p21uxt p22u t p21ext/p11 p22u t Here we get rid of the second, u_pit, also using expression for u_xt e t p21ext/p11 p22 u t And we are done. u_it now entirely in terms of knowns.

  14. Impulse responses to the structural shocks 1u u B0e e B0 irf AhB0e Yh We can use the reduced form VAR estimates to compute the response to structural shocks. Our structural shocks are functions of the reduced form shocks, a function of our assumed value for B_0. So we then feed these through the reduced form VAR in the normal way, taking successively higher and higher powers of the A matrix.

  15. Problems with recursive structure implied by Cholesky identification Is it economically plausible? Quarterly data. Does output or inflation really not respond to interest rates within the quarter? Assumed causal ordering means we can t use the VAR to find out about causality. Common practice to check for robustness to alternative causal orderings, but this is rarely done comprehensively; and [so Kilian says] is nonsensical!

  16. Recap on causal assumptions in Cholesky identification of mon pol shock Neither e_x nor e_pi are functions of the structural shock u_it. 0 0 ex e ei p11 p21 p22 p31 p32 p33 ux u ui 0 Implies output gap and inflation do not respond [within the period] to a monetary policy shock. t t t E t 1 xt u t xt Ext 1 it E t 1 uxt it t xxt uit Is this really plausible? Remember the NK DSGE model. If we trace the timing of the effects of the monetary policy shock, we can see that it affects inflation and the output gap straight away. Of course, the NK model could be a load of nonsense!

  17. More problems with recursive identification. Sims and the price puzzle . Would find that recursively identified, contract mon pol shock leads to increase in prices, contrary to theory. Concluded that had omitted variable cb responding to, eg commodity prices. CP up means prices up, despite central bank rate increase.

  18. Recursive ID problems: omitted variables Omitted variable bias leads us to enlarge the VAR. But there is a cost: imprecision in the coefficients. And the search for more restrictions. Solutions: Bayesian shrinkage and factor modelling to reduce dimensionality. In time we will cover both of these.

  19. What are these mp shocks anyway? Why would policymakers induce shocks? Are they really conducting experiments for their own edification [a control literature involving Sargent, Cogley shows there is a benefit]. Alan Blinder says not. Shocks are just misspecifications by econometrician Shocks are policymakers real time measurement error? Shocks are policymakers [or our] model mis- specification Same goes, of course, for fiscal policy shocks.

  20. Alternative, less intensive measures of identifying (eg) mp shocks Romer and Romer (1989) narrative measures of monetary policy (and fiscal policy) shocks. Rudebusch (1998): gap between actual Fed Funds Rate and expectations implied by Fed Funds futures.

  21. Romer and Romers narrative shock definition Problem: they are including movements in rates prompted by concerns about inflation. So if we think i=a*pi+b*y+shock, they are not identifying m p shocks

  22. Romer and Romer(1989), quoting Friedman and Schwartz (1964)

  23. Rudebusch, and Sims on Rudebusch Rudebusch: FFFs produce better forecasts than VARs. His surprise a better measure of policy shocks . Sims (1996): 1. False premise. FFR shocks confound surprises due to non policy shocks with those due to shocks. 2. Not true that if shock measures badly correlated, estimated effects are very different.

  24. Famous applications Rotemburg and Woodford (1998). Early application. Estimated DSGE model by fitting IRFs of monetary policy shock using MDE. Later pointed out that in DSGE model EVERYTHING responds within the period to monetary policy. Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (2005) Same exercise. But DSGE model is consistent with timing assumption.

  25. Minimum distance estimation mde argmin Y Y A, e DSGE model is defined by a vector of parameters, PHI. We take as our PHI_hat the value of these parameters that makes the impulse response in the DSGE model as close as possible to the identified, estimated IRF in the VAR. Some costs and benefits wrt eg MLE estimation of DSGE model. Cost: partial information, means bad identification. Benefit: MLE only consistent if model well-specified.

  26. Identification using long run restrictions Attractive because much agreement on certain long run restrictions. So these are credible in Sims language. At least among members of the RBC/DSGE cult [like me]! Famous early applications are Blanchard and Quah (1989), and Gali (1999). More later. Technique sparked famous arguments between Chari et al and VAR proponents, notably Christiano and coauthors.

  27. Egs of restrictions uncontroversial, at least in DSGE/RBC-land Nominal shocks should have no long run impact on real variables. Corrollary: only real shocks should have a long run impact on real variables. Real shocks like technology should be neutral on inflation in the long run. Only inflation regime changes should affect inflation in the long run.

  28. Deriving long run restrictions for an SVAR Reduced form VAR(1) with an expression in terms of structural shocks and the unkown structural impact matrix substiuted in place of the RF shock 1ut Yt At 1 B0 1 impact period: B0 1 period after: AB0 2 periods after:A2B0 nperiods after:AnB0 This is how we would compute the IRF to the structural shock, if only we knew the structural impat matrix.... 1 1 1 You can see this defines an infinite sequence. Effect on level of something=0, implies sum of effects on difference=0.

  29. Deriving long run restrictions 1 AB0 1 A2B0 1 ... AnB0 1 1 D B0 I A A2 ...An B0 D I A 1B0 Factor the long run IRF in terms of something you might recognise from high school as the expression for an infinite geometric series, or its matrix equivalent. 1 i 0 1 ai 1 a Some algebra and we spot that DD involves something we can estimate from the data, the vcov of the RF residuals! 1B0 1 I A 1 DD I A 1B0 I A 1 e I A 1

  30. Long run restrictions and the Cholesky factor, again 1B0 1 I A 1 DD I A 1B0 DD which we know to be related to the magic B0 which we are trying to find we also know to be related entirely to things we do know. I A 1 e I A 1 D chol I A 1 e I A 1 1 I A 1 D B0 B0 1 I A D

  31. Galis (AER, 1999) search for technology shocks log yt/ht log ht Yt Only the tech shock (which we say comes first, has a long run effect on the first variable, (the change in) output per hour 0 d11 d21 d22 D

  32. Celebrated applications of LR restrictions Blanchard-Quah. Tech shock is the only thing to affect output in the long run. Q: how important are tech shocks in driving the business cycle? Gali (1999). Tech shock is only thing driving labour productivity. Appears to cause hours to fall, not rise. Consistent with sticky price model, not RBC models. Hours tend to comove positively with business cycle. Suggests tech shocks not dominant driver of business cycle. Christiano-Eichenbaum-Vigfussen (). Reexamination of Gali. Conclusion depends on definition of hours worked used in VAR

  33. Identification of VARs using sign restrictions 1 0 0 0 e PP ,P chol e e PCC P ,C Givens 0 c s 0 ,c cos ,s sin 0 s 0 c 0 0 0 1 Cholesky factorisation of rf varcov can be expanded with product of any orthonormal matrix So, parameterising with the angle theta, we choose all those that satisfy certain sign restrictions sign S.PCAh R Sign is the signum function; S is a selector matrix with ones for restricted elements, 0s otherwise. C is our givens matrix. A is our estimated rf impact matrix.

  34. Signum function and the selector matrix An example of what the signum function does to a matrix. Turns things into 0s, 1s or -1s. Just a way to record in an algorithm whether things are positive, negative or zero. Could do it differently, with more if, then else statements. 0 0.05 0 1 sign 2 3 1 1 2 6 1 0 2 6 2 0 S. . 0 1 1 0 0 1 0 0 An example of doing element by element multiplication with a selector matrix.

  35. Verbal description of sign restrictions Take cholesky factor of vcov matrix P Multiply by some Givens, C(theta) Check signs of elements of interest. If they agree with your restrictions, store and keep. If not, move on. At the end, plot ALL the IRFs, and or summarise them somehow.

  36. i=cb rate, pi=inflation, x=output, ur=unemployment rate it t xt urt Yt AYt 1 et Mp shock in first column: contraction raises rate, lowers pi, lowers output, lowers unemployment. 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 R 1 1 1 0 Tech shock in second column: reduction has ambiguous effect on i, increases pi, lowers output, ambiguous effect on ue 1 0 1 0 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 S Demand shock in third column: cb raises rates to fight it, inflation and output increase anyway, ue falls. 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 Fourth shock unidentified. A dustbin containing many things we don t need to worry about. 0 c s 0 C 0 s 0 c 0 0 0 1

  37. Alternative way to do sign restrictions using the QR decomposition 1.LKK,Lij NID 0,1 2.L QR,QQ IK 3.C Q 4.Proceed as before Any square matrix can be decomposed into a product of an orthonormal matrix and something else. Matlab will calculate this for you in a flash. Note equivalence which seems not to be widely understood. Derives from fact that all orthonormal matrices can be shown to be product of Givens matrices. Personal preference: use Givens method. Systematic way to explore the space. Random number generators for step 1 in computers are not random, they are pseudo random. Don t know if this matters much.

  38. Sign restrictions at different or multiple horizons Choose h the horizon, then keep IRF if it satisifies this condition sign SPC Ah R sign SPC Ah1 R,sign SPC Ah2 R For multiple horizons, keep if the condition above applied for multiple horizons holds!

  39. Warning: spanning the entire space of possible impulse responses A givens indexed by one angle only not enough to guarantee to find all possible IRFs that satisfy the sign restriction, except in the 2 variable case [eg n=2, 2*(1)/2=1] n n 1 /2 n n 1 /2 More generally, we need to search across orthonormal matrices formed by products of Givens matrices. i 1 C i

  40. Reporting distributions from sign restrictions n IRFh 1/n irf 1.For eachh compute: Yh, i i 1 2 2. Find argmin h Yh, i irf IRFh irf 3. Plot Yh, Sign restrictions generate arbitrary numbers of impulse response functions. How to report them? Can just plot the whole damned lot. People used to report moments at each h eg the median. Fry and Pagan suggested above. Find the single SVAR corresponding to single angle that is closest to this median.

  41. Sign restrictions: examples Giraitis, Kapetanios, Yates. Actually a TVP study, but don t worry about that until later on in the lecture series. Sign restrictions to identify various shocks. Studies time variation in the IRFs.

  42. Sign restrictions in Giraitis, Kapetanios, Yates w/p r c i y h monetarypolicy - - - - technology - labour supply - - demand

  43. Identification using Mountford and Uhlig s penalty method 1. drawrotationmatrixC H 2. compute K wh SPCAh Vh SPCAh Vh h 1 3. Rank according to K w_h are weights; V records not just signs, but magnitudes. Why would you do this? Isn t it just assuming the answer? Well, one motivation is to use one implication of the model to test another, that you don t impose. Another is that some rotations may satisfy the sign restriction literally, but you want the IRF not just to clear the zero line by a tiny amount.

  44. Using the max share criterion in a VAR to identify news shocks Barsky-Sims (2010): identified news shocks for technology. Long history of identifying technology shocks, measuring impact, quantifying contribution to business cycles RE assumption suggests agents may also react to news about future events. Failure to account for this may mislead us in properly measuring and quantifying effects of technology shocks.

  45. Other work on news shocks Beaudry-Portier: news shocks in VARs: news causes hours to increase. Jaimovich and Rebello: news shocks in RBC model, neutralising the wealth effect so that hours don t fall. Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2012): multiple news shocks in large RBC style model Christiano, Motto, Rostagno and Pinter, Theodoridis and Yates: risk news shocks in DSGE model and VAR respectively

  46. News shocks: algebra yt B L ut ut A AA t h yt h Et 1yt h B AQ t h 0 IN, K K 1 /2 1 Q Q 1 Q 2 ... Q K K 1 /2 1 Q Q A chol Note annoying change of notation; matches Barsky-Sims. Sorry. Good for the soul though. This slide is about writing down the expression for the forecast error up to horizon h.

  47. News shocks identification, ctd... The share of the FEV up to horizon h, of variable i, accounted for by shock j... B ei h ei 0 B AQ ejej Q A i,j h h ei 0 B B ei Example news process for tfp. Could be more general than this. news tfpt tfpt 1 utfp,t utfp,t 1 1,1 h 1,2 h 1 In an ideal setting, share of current and news shock to tfp that accounts for tfp should be 1. tfp is exogenous after all!

  48. News shocks: the max share criterion By choice of the K.(K-1)/2 vector of angles w, maximise the share of tfp forecast error variance up to horizon h, accounted for by the news shock to tfp, subject to the restriction that the news shock is orthogonal to tfp today. [if it weren t, it wouldn t be news, it would be a contemp. Shock to tfp] max i,j h subject to A 1,j 0,j 1 In Pinter, Theodoridis and Yates, in our search for risk news shocks, we impose a sign restrictions condition too. sign SA 22 F

More Related Content

giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#