Innovation in Low and Medium Technology Sectors

 
Innovation in Low and Medium
Technology (LMT) Sectors
 
 
Low-tech’’ industry…ore than just a matter of
semantics
 
It is crucial for understanding where the 
comparative advantages of
countries 
at varying levels of development may lie.
Policy obsession with ‘‘gaps’’ in ‘‘high-tech’’ industries has
distracted the attention
 of both policy makers and academics away
from making more positive efforts to develop and sustain
development in other sectoral direction s which some countries might
find more viable.
High-tech industries in the 
OECD account for only about 3 per cent 
of value-
added rising to 8.5 per cent with medium-high-tech industries like car industry
Governments need to give more thought to the activities which generate most
of the output and employment of their countries and the best targets for
‘‘dynamic comparative advantage’’ for growth.
 
Labour and capital…
 
The LMT industries are usually regarded as providing many points of
entry for developing countries, in view of their relative labor-intensity
(e.g. software in India).
Some branches of such ‘‘low-tech’’ industries as food processing are
highly capital-intensive (e.g. tobacco and many beverages), as are
some branches of building materials (e.g. cement).
It also depend on the specific context (es. U.S.A. vs India).
 
Conventional classification
 
N
ot just traditional ‘‘low-tech’’ industries but also those classified by the OECD as
‘‘medium-tech”  (= ‘‘low- and medium-tech’’, LMT
 i
ndustries.):
 
Mature industries; more slow changes; included non-manufacturing activities
(e.g. Oil and Gas); sometimes integrated with “services”…
 
Conventional classifications of sectors as high- or low-tech (etc.), as long practised
by the OECD, are becoming less and less useful for academic analysis
 
To be fair, the OECD (2003) came - rightly—to place greater emphasis on the
‘‘knowledge-intensity
’’ of industries.
 
Measuring  the 
direct plus indirect technology content 
of particular industries.
 
 
What is a LMT Sector and what innovation in it?
 
Appraising innovation through adopting conventional sectoral
classifications can be misleading
.
Innovation is rapid in 
particular segments 
of both high-tech and LMT
‘‘sectors,’’ (even if more segments of the high-tech sectors display
such rapid innovation)
It is  possible to detach the high-tech segments from LMT
‘‘industries’’ : e.g.  Artificial fibers in textiles when they arose to
compete with natural fibers but the final products remain very similar,
so this looks specious….
.
 
 
What are we talking about?
 
Conventionally, sectors of all types were supposed to be 
different not
only in the goods and services
 
but also in the technologies and
processes
 they used to produce them. 
However…
The 
boundaries have blurred 
over historical time in both dimensions….
Technologies originally developed for one set of products 
spill over
 into use in
the production or ‘‘architecture’’ of other sets of products.
new technologies more often tend to 
supplement and complement old
technologies
 
rather than replace 
them.
even ‘‘old’’ products can be produced by elements drawn from what had
previously been a totally different set of activities (e.g. synthetic fibers in
textiles).
bundling of goods and services 
(music on internet)
 
 
 
Innovation drivers in LMT industries
1) The «demand»
 
The 
drivers of change 
as they affect low, medium, and high-tech sectors can
be similarly envisaged from the side:
1.
 of the products (and the demand!)
2.
or from  the side of the technologies
…significant differences in interpretation and understanding.
Firms hold different interpretative ‘‘frames”, and 
drivers
 are particularly
important because their 
well-established markets, 
necessitate a broader
variety of strategic choices for differentiation.
Demands change 
sometimes slowly but sometimes rapidly and
unpredictably, negating attempts to routinize operations and generating
turbulence.
 
A) Demand differentiation: 1) quality innovation
and 2) new tastes
 
1)
Quality innovation
a) New markets
Even older industries can bounce back, by producing for 
new markets
.
The same type of goods for untouched regions can work for well-known
brands (Coca-Cola)
…but producing different types of the same categories of good (‘‘product
differentiation’’) is generally necessary for such resurgence.
Low-tech industries face somewhat inelastic demands (many produce
comparative ‘‘necessities,’’ and as consumers attain higher income
levels, they have satisfed most of their needs for necessities).
 
 
b) New scope for new products (also through technolgy)
To stave off this ‘‘satiation of wants,’’ producers in LMT industries
have to find 
new products 
to attract the custom of higher earners.
The 
availability of advanced technologies 
may be an important factor
for innovation strategies in LMT firms through dictating the scope for
such new products.
Even then may not result in products that customers find attractive, as has
been the case for genetically  modified foodstuffs in some countries.
In addition to quality upgrading, consumers may switch their demand
patterns to goods which have 
new characteristics
.
E.g. Auto/food/Energy: intense pressure from communities and from
governments to produce safer and more environmentally friendly items.
Adding value in processing (e.g. sensors in tires)
S
hifts in product mixes to 
reflect the changing composition of
consumers
, for example the implications of demographic change
(gender relations, ageing, etc.).
 
What defininition to be used?
 
Approaches
 (= classification; taxonomy, etc.) that blend the 
technology
dimension and the 
product 
dimension, appear to be:
more analytically satisfying
better able to account for observed empirical differences between countries and
regions
better able to account for dynamic paths of industrial evolution over historical time.
They need however to be supplemented by 
technology-oriented
distinctions
 among sectors (e.g. Pavitt taxonomy) to provide a better grasp
of the nature of structural change and competitiveness.
Furthermore, they are in our view a more advisable platform for policy than
simple “OECD-style” definitions of high- or low-tech.
 
Some problems in defining technology!
 
The majority of manufacturing industries are defined mostly
according to their product range…
…but a good number 
have in common their technologies rather than
their products
,
E.g. 
biotechnology
. - plant biotechnology is regarded as part of the
biotechnology industry (technology-defined) or of agriculture (product-
defined) makes a big difference to the inferences drawn.
Moreover… innovation activities in LMT tend to fall outside
conventional definition of R&D activities (es. OECD Frascati Manual)
 
 a) “General Purpose Technologies” 
and Learning in LMT Firms
Key technologies often have the property of being able to become
‘‘pervasive’’ (they can spill out of their industry of origin and be recruited
by older industries)
M
achinery, steam power, and iron (I Industrial Revolution)…information
and communication technologies, biotechnology and smart materials in
the III IR (= General Purpose Techn
ologies)
.
III created 
new opportunities 
for LMT industries to enhance their
innovative and economic performance through new technologies
However, in LMT industries there is usually 
little formal learning by science
and technology, at least at the 
fi
rm level (innovation and adoption operate
in 
practical and pragmatic ways by doing and using
)
 
Innovation drivers in LMT industries
2) New Technological Paradigms
 
The absorptive capacity and the R&D function
 
The bulk of the general-purpose technologies, are developed by separate
companies (rarely subsidiaries), specialized in the relevant technological
fields.
However the downstream LMT industries need to have ‘‘absorptive
capacities’’ to 
make productive use of these upstream developments
.
food-processing companies involved in advanced (‘‘third-generation’’) biotechnology
do not carry out much of the associated research themselves but are often
prominent in patenting in less advanced (‘‘second-generation’’) biotechnology—this
seems to provide them with the necessary absorptive capabilities.
F
ormal science may congregate in national or regional laboratories in such
industries, instead of being internalized within 
fi
rms
Innovation require firm-speciWc absorptive capacities, generated not just from
formal R&D but from broader-based innovative activities that include engineering,
continuous improvement processes, and organizational innovations such as
integrated service and supply.
 
Carrier Industries (general purpose techn.)
 
Describing one particular industry supplying technologies, namely machine
tools, Rosenberg (1963) showed how the number of different 
types of tools
was quite limited and as a result their principles could readily be stretched
to being applied in industries other than where they were first deployed.
Signifcant role of ‘‘carrier industries,’’ which incorporated these
proliferating machine tools into making the machines they produced or
used (producing machines related to those “tools”).
“general purpose technologies”: any industry can act as a carrier if its
demand for the new capital good is large enough or growing fast enough.
Thus even low-tech sectors can act as receptors for new process-oriented
technologies (e.g. machine tools for 3d printers).
 
«Research» in LMT industries.
 
Knowledge search, identification and proof, rather than basic
research, are likely to be of particular importance to innovation in the
non-manufacturing activities of LMT industries.
We have to ask 
what part of each ‘‘industry’’ 
we are characterizing as
high- or low-tech when considering their growth potential  advantage
In low-growth sectors (such as processed foods)…innovation lies towards the
high-tech end of these low-growth sectors (like applying biotechnology to
food processing).
 
 
More useful (complex) taxonomies…
1) 
Peneder
 
Peneder (2001): 
“tripartite” classification 
(but starting form
“Product”)
1.
one of his taxonomies 
rests on factor intensity 
(mainstream i.e.
average; labor-intensive; capital-intensive; marketing-driven;
technology-intensive),
2.
another on 
labour skills 
(low-skill; medium-skill blue-collar;
medium-skill white-collar; high-skill),
3.
and the 
third on external service inputs 
(from knowledge-based
services; from retail and advertising services; from transport
services; and from other industries).
 
1b) …Peneder Taxonomy
 
Only one of the ninety-nine manufacturing industries Peneder lists
(“aircraft and spacecraft”) has the classic high-tech profile of being:
technology-intensive 
and
 predominantly using high-skill 
and
knowledge-based services!
Conversely, there are labor-intensive industries which utilize high skills
(e.g. machine tools) and others utilizing knowledge-based service
inputs (some branches of metallurgy).
His classification underlines the 
great variety of observable
combinations
.
 
2) The Pavit Taxonomy (1984) of sectoral
innovation patterns 
(see also chaptera on SIS)
 
Pavitt (1984) proposes four types of sectoral pattern for innovative activities.
I.
In 
supplier-dominated (e.g. textile, services) sectors
, new technologies are embodied
in new components and equipment, and the diffusion of new technologies and
learning takes place through learning-by-doing and by-using.
II.
In 
scale-intensive sectors (e.g. autos, steel)
, process innovation is relevant and the
sources of innovation are both internal (R&D and learning-by-doing) and external
(equipment producers), while appropriability is obtained through secrecy and patents.
III.
In 
specialized suppliers 
(e.g. equipment producers), innovation is focused on
performance improvement, reliability, and customization, with the sources of
innovation being both internal (tacit knowledge and experience of skilled technicians)
and external (user–producer interaction); appropriability comes mainly from the
localized and interactive nature of knowledge.
IV.
Finally, science-based sectors 
(e.g. pharmaceuticals, electronics) are characterized by
a high rate of product and process innovations, by internal R&D, and by scientifc
research done at universities and public research laboratories; science is a source of
innovation, and appropriability means are of various types, ranging from patents, to
lead-times and learning curves,
 
Difficulties in classifying LMT!
 
Pavitt (and others, as Marsili) deliberately aimed at means of
classification that brought together characteristics which certain
groups of technologies appeared to share, even though they might
pertain to different ‘‘sectors.’’
Generally this taxonomies do a better job of 
explaining technological
performance 
than factor content…
..However, again, the LMT industries resist easy classification,
precisely because many of them are not very distinctive or singular in
technological terms
.
For instance: growing export industries sprinkled all first four
categories of Pavitt taxonomy!
 
3) The Sutton taxonomy: relationships with
the industry/market structure
 
Sutton: firms are prepared to spend on 
marketing their products 
on
the one hand, and on 
developing their technologies
 on the other
(trad-off)…It depends on factors that were partly under a firm’s
control and partly beyond it!
Sutton approach and associated taxonomy can be especially
useful for analyzing LMT industries, because supply (technology) is
combined with
demand (product) aspects in a rigorous way.
 
E.g. The tire industry
 
E.g. 
Tire industry 
-  Sunk costs; heavy market concentration;  Capital intensive;
large scale; not strong changes in basic technology (rubber) – Global 
Oligopolistic
structure!
Technology is applied by the tire manufacturers to 
reduce costs,
 to 
differentiate
the product 
line and to focus on 
greater value-adding activities 
(Acha and
Brusoni 2003). Complexity in the nature of Knowledge Basis;
Interface between chemical knowledge base (rubber) and “others”  (sensors,
electronics, car engineering, etc.)
Facing a global market where it is more and more difficult to make a profit, the
leading manufacturers are continuously focusing on reducing costs through
reducing throughput and labor costs (including the long-awaited introduction of
robotics
), 
innovations in processing technologies 
and source product (a new
polyurethane tire polymer), and in the method itself (e.g. 
sensors in tires
). Beyond
influencing the cost and ease of production, tire manufacturers have invested in
research and technology to also help them 
to move away from the ‘‘commodity
trap
,’’ where products can only compete on price. (e.g. also marketing: 
colored
tires
!). Or moving up the value chain by 
manufacturing entire tire assembly
systems. High-tech providers; Patents; High R&D rates
 
F
i
 
r
 
m
 
s
 
 
a
 
n
 
d
 
C
o
 
r
 
p
 
o
 
r
 
a
 
t
 
e
 
C
h
 
a
 
n
 
g
 
e
i
 
n
 
L
 
M
 
T
 
 
I
n
 
d
 
u
 
s
 
t
 
r
 
i
 
e
 
s
 
= Issues concerning 
strategies and structures 
at the firm level (economies of scale
and scope; vert./horiz. Integration) in both large firms and SMEs: relations with
technologies and innovation processes
 
STRATEGIES
A) orthodox vision
Porter (1985) –: three main types of corporate strategy, namely: a) cost leadership,
b) differentiation; c) focus.
cost leadership 
is the likely “choice” of firms in a ‘‘mature’’ LMT industry (process
innovation “only” to pare down costs even) 
.
B) Alternative points of view: technology related also to….
Branding
 (product reputation) is often crucial to the choice of a differentiation
strategy (e.g. Skoda is nowadays using advertising of its new technologies to change
deep-seated customer prejudices);
Focus
 in terms of multidivisional firm (many focused markets): it may rise several
problems…(if there are spillovers between the same functions located in different
divisions)
 
Why Porter approach is not valid in interpreeting
the technology issue in LMT industries?
 
In contrast to the orthodox vision (Porter),  in practice, managers
consider particular activities rather than “the whole” (“corporate
strategy”) at once.
A 
technology frame 
(and not a pure strategic frame)
, therefore, is the
actual interpretative system of managers to understand the firm
technological position and innovation opportunities!
Oil and Gas industry: there is little direct correlation between formal technological
performance (say patenting and scientific publications) and business performance (say
expansion or profitability), unless this intervening variable of the frame is accounted for
by managers!
 
 
The «technology frame» concept
 
The frame concept is relevant to the study of innovation in LMTsectors.
Firms in LMT industries are 
basically using rather than selling technology
, and
therefore tend to adopt technology frames that are:
a)
quite different from those in high-tech industries (where technology itself is a
key selling point),
b)
and often quite different from other LMT firms even in the same industry.
In general, the market characteristics of LMT industries (segmentation,
differentiation, etc.) lead firms to 
different interpretations about the role for
technology for commercial success.
 
In ‘‘high-tech’’ firms, by contrast, the role for technology is more central to commercial
success, and there may be greater tendencies for consensus (general or by groups) on
aspects of technology frames across these competing firms
 
variation in technology frames across ‘‘high-tech’’ firms derives more from a focus on how
the technology (broadly stated) should develop, whereas variation in technology frames
amongst LMT firms pertains more to what the role for technology (broadly stated) should be.
 
 
Scale and Scope in LMT industries and
technology: Large Firms and SMEs
 
Some mature ‘‘LMT’’ industries (as meatpacking, automobile production, and
consumer durables, etc.) were important sources of production innovation in their
early years
It is (partially) true that driving force of mass production was to reap
economies of scale
” in the production processes, and the M-form
(multidivisional) company was a very suitable organizational form for doing
so…
However, 
‘‘time-saving’’  
was a very relevant way to get economies: t
his
was achieved through 
raising throughput
, 
reducing downtime
, and
improving the machinery
‘‘
Dynamic economies of scale,’’ 
not usual “static scale economies” arising,
for instance, out of having large plant!
 
New ways to get dynamic economies of scale
 
LARGE COMPANIES
decline in average establishment size (
‘minimills’’)
system of ‘‘lean production’’ (e.g. Toyota) - which was a response to
the needs of customers for variety and specialization while sacrificing
as little as possible of the benefits of high throughput; Just in time,
etc.
‘‘dynamic economies of scope’’ to balance loss of standardization;
Long run conversion process, but innovation and technology often
related to those targets!
 
 
 
SMEs innovation potential (in LMT industries)
 
Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) have reappeared on
government technology policy agendas.
Renewed emphasis as possible sources of innovation (perceived
advantage of SMEs in responding quickly to technological change,
because of the absence of complex management structures within
smaller enterprises).
Against that, SMEs may lack the 
fi
nancial power to undertake the
kinds of investments in new technologies
Questions of access to new technologies and on what terms; they are
often (perhaps unfairly) seen as a “matter for despair” in LMT
sectors.;
 
Vertical and horizontal integration
 
The LMT industries have been characterized by 
a variety of patterns of
vertical integration and disintegration through their development across
time
.
1.
At the beginning
, high degree of vertical stratification (not integration) -
segments interact in systemic fashion with one another through the
vertical ‘‘chains.’’ – 
imbalances in development affecting the value
chain
….
2.
In the second phase 
of industrialization there were pressures to link the
segmented processes (vertical integration. The pressures of throughput
that gave rise to ‘‘mass production’’; smooth production flows
throughout the value chain).
3.
More recently
, the rise of the “steel minimill”, partly from technical
change, at the expense of the large integrated mill has been one of the
more dramatic demonstrations of a retreat from vertical integration (see
before).
 
 
 
 
 
Recent trends at firm level
 
Tasks previously undertook have been ‘‘outsourced’’, thereby returning to the
traditional low-tech model of vertical disintegration even in some high-tech
industries.
To retain and intensify the economies of scope required in this unfolding set of
circumstances, companies also chose to limit the range of their horizontal
diversification.
 ‘downsizing’’ and in many cases stripped out large numbers of middle
management in the belief that this furthered ‘‘lean production.’’
While financial considerations had often encouraged diversification into
unrelated activities, studies demonstrated that ‘‘conglomerate’’ firms based on
unrelated diversification were not very profitable..
Taking on board the technological and production aspects, and thereby taking
into account the issues of synergies and economies of scope, many firms
reoriented their structure to limit themselves to ‘‘related’’ diversification.
Yet many of the larger companies in low-tech industries like food manufacturing continue to
pursue apparently unrelated diversification: low technological opportunity in traditional
segments of low-tech industries may also go with relatively high appropriability, especially
through branding (
rather than 
through technology!)
 
 
Dynamic changes at 
industry
 level:
Vertical Alignment and Networks
 
Changes at the 
fi
rm level in terms of size, integration and diversification carry
strong implications for the structure of the industries.
To overcome hierarchical control, firms have been driven to develop closer
relationships with upstream suppliers and downstream customers.
Toyota system: high reliance on suppliers to deliver on time and of high quality; joint
development with the supplier; long periods of time negotiating the exact specifications
and costings; first-tier’ (or second tier, etc.)  suppliers worked in close association with
Toyota wherever the production was located, as “Systems integrators” hat is,
Each integrator would be surrounded by a network of suppliers and related activities.
New power balance emerge;
In the lower-tech industries especially, like textiles and some branches of food,
the 
manufacturing stages of the ‘‘chain’’ were squeezed 
as power tended to
shift downstream to the 
fi
nal stages and even to the retailers.
 
Industrial patterns
 
How do industries differ in their behavior?; Can one observe different
patterns in LMT industries than high-tech industries at the industry and
sector levels?
Are the Schumpeter “Marks” relevant and useful?
What results if you adopt the SIS approach (Malerba)?
key conditions: opportunity, appropriability, cumulativeness, and knowledge base).
Clothing
 falls o into the category of Mark I, characterized by low
technological opportunity
, weak 
appropriability 
of any innovations, small
firms and 
rapid entry 
and exit, 
practical rather than scientific knowledge
base.
Motor vehicles 
as a medium-tech industry have greater technological
opportunities, greater appropriability and the persistence (cumulativness) of
large firms.
 
Technological opportunities and outsourcing…
 
Some of the lowtech industries are Mark I but others are nearer to Mark II,
while food-processing resists any easy classification since its sub-branches
operate in a whole variety of ways.
Where demand plays such a large role, 
market opportunity 
can be as
important as 
technological opportunity
, and may be very diVerent in extent
as well as in nature.
Fast-growing areas of consumption are not always the same as fast-growing areas of
technology, as noted above.
However, technological opportunities may be enlarging again for ‘‘low-
tech’’ industries, although 
fi
rms will for the most part outsource the
development of these new technologies
. Outsourcing may limit
opportunities for ‘‘user’’ 
fi
rms to appropriate the returns from innovation
that relies on this approach
 
LMT and appropriability within the supply
chain
 
In the supplier-dominated low-tech industries (as defined by Pavitt) the
appropriability of technologies rests upon the division of power between
the technology developers—the upstream suppliers— and the users, like
food or clothing companies.
These activities are rarely vertically integrated, because the suppliers
usually wish to supply a variety of users both within the same activity and
outside.
The appropriability of the products depends on both the marketing
endeavours of the companies concerned, and the power balance vis-a`- vis
downstream distributors and retailers.
Links with technology suppliers tend to be much more distant than in high-
tech sectors.
 
Techn. accumulation: entries and exits
 
Many LMT industries are characterized by 
high levels of ‘‘turbulence
,’’
with a churning of entry and exit.
These pose the issue of “learning” in turbulent environments—if new
entrants may simply replicate their predecessors’ mistakes!
In North American environments at least, the individuals concerned do tend
to go on to form another firm…
Alternatively the continuity can be maintained by technological
dependence 
on a large supplier 
or an 
industrial district
 (e.g. clothing.)
In complex products systems, where alliances are reconstituted for
each new project, learning is achieved by the flux of interactions of
the constituent firms, although a high level of ‘‘forgetting’’ also seems
to be common..
 
Final message…
 
The dichotomous Mark I and II categorizations may be too restrictive
to portray the main patterns of evolution of diVerent industries, and
more complex schema such as that of Pavitt (1984) or Malerba may
be preferable for understanding the impact of differing technologies.
 
Dynemic Competition in time
 
Across the full range of industries, the modern era is supposed to be
characterized by competition that has intensified because of globalization
and because of more rapid change in market demand.
In LMT industries the 
pace of change and competition may be less intense,
as market leaders seek to retain their predominance by 
brand loyalty
.
Marketing-based appropriability offsets some of the pressures to develop
new products.
However frms in LMT industries are also susceptible to innovations that
accelerate the development times (‘‘cycle time’’) and rate of application
and diffusion for new technologies (e.g. ICT for customer service)
 
Governamental Policies:
 
Government technology policies at national and supranational levels have
on the whole 
tended to give the highest priority to high-tech sectors and
activities (benchmark = share of HT activities).
Such a benchmark falls into the 
trap of confusing the sector with the
technology level.
Traditional innovation policy: ‘‘linear model’’ of “technology-push”.
Although this approach does not preclude applications of high technology to more
traditional fields, in fact focus is on “new sectors”
On the other side, 
for many decades 
the bias towards such technologies
was also coupled to one towards consolidation of (LMT) firms and
industries, seen as ‘‘
national champions
’’ for technological and
commercial success.
In recent times
, 
SMEs
 have been increasingly thought of as progenitors of
high technology, in fields such as biotechnology and genomics, software,
advanced instrumentation, and so on. 
Yet in low-tech industries, SMEs are
most widely seen as dragging down overall performance
.
 
 
Rebalancing…
 
The antithesis of the ‘‘supply–push’’ contribution of the linear model is 
the
‘‘demand–pull’’ approach to innovation
, in which the causal sequence is
reversed.
Governments, though, tend to be loath to 
‘‘leave it all to market forces,’’
in an arena in which ‘‘market failures’’ are so evidently present as they are
in innovative activities.
While this may not overcome all the market failure shortcomings, there
there is room for 
rebalancing policy
 in such a way as to place 
greater
stress on the Technology diffusion aspects
.
diffusion of high-tech activities into “supposedly” low-tech sectors: there is a much
wider scope for such migration of technologies across sectoral boundaries than is
often supposed.
 
Locked countries…
 
A perhaps even larger number of countries have become locked into the
low-tech activities and never adequately escaped, as is often alleged for
Latin America.
The difficulty remains that countries’ comparative advantages often remain
indissolubly linked to the low-tech sectors.
Key message: there are no true low-tech sectors in the modern world
however overrides this. 
It is perfectly possible to diffuse high technologies
into the ‘‘low-tech sectors”
In that way, intermediate and developing 
countries do not need to face a dilemma
when choosing between:
static comparative advantage 
in traditional fields
and 
dynamic comparative advantage from technological opportunity
! —
Opportunities from: downstreaming diffusion of high-tech activities into ‘‘low-tech
sectors,’’ and from the lateral diffusion of old technological Welds into new ones.
 
 
Countries like 
Switzerland
 developed, consciously or unconsciously, a
pattern of evolution that went—in this case—from textiles to dyeing and
chemicals and then into 
strength in pharmaceuticals 
on the one hand, and
into machinery and thence to advanced engineering 
on the other.
A clear implication of these policy considerations is that strength in low-
tech sectors does not have to act as a ‘‘block to development,’’ although
national and supranational governments frequently embody this error in
their technology policies.
The ‘‘block to development’’ view can be replaced by a ‘‘
development
block
’’ view, in which 
LMT sectors act as ‘‘carrier industries
’’ for diffusing
the gains from new technologies across the industrial spectrum, as they
have so often managed to do in the past
Slide Note
Embed
Share

Understanding the significance of innovation in low and medium technology sectors is crucial for economic development. Traditional classifications like high-tech and low-tech are evolving as innovation blurs sector boundaries. The focus should be on identifying areas with dynamic comparative advantages for sustained growth.

  • Innovation
  • Low-Tech
  • Medium-Tech
  • Comparative Advantage
  • Economic Development

Uploaded on Sep 25, 2024 | 0 Views


Download Presentation

Please find below an Image/Link to download the presentation.

The content on the website is provided AS IS for your information and personal use only. It may not be sold, licensed, or shared on other websites without obtaining consent from the author. Download presentation by click this link. If you encounter any issues during the download, it is possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Innovation in Low and Medium Technology (LMT) Sectors

  2. Low-tech industryore than just a matter of semantics It is crucial for understanding where the comparative advantages of countries at varying levels of development may lie. Policy obsession with gaps in high-tech industries has distracted the attention of both policy makers and academics away from making more positive efforts to develop and sustain development in other sectoral direction s which some countries might find more viable. High-tech industries in the OECD account for only about 3 per cent of value- added rising to 8.5 per cent with medium-high-tech industries like car industry Governments need to give more thought to the activities which generate most of the output and employment of their countries and the best targets for dynamic comparative advantage for growth.

  3. Labour and capital The LMT industries are usually regarded as providing many points of entry for developing countries, in view of their relative labor-intensity (e.g. software in India). Some branches of such low-tech industries as food processing are highly capital-intensive (e.g. tobacco and many beverages), as are some branches of building materials (e.g. cement). It also depend on the specific context (es. U.S.A. vs India).

  4. Conventional classification Not just traditional low-tech industries but also those classified by the OECD as medium-tech (= low- and medium-tech , LMT industries.): Mature industries; more slow changes; included non-manufacturing activities (e.g. Oil and Gas); sometimes integrated with services Conventional classifications of sectors as high- or low-tech (etc.), as long practised by the OECD, are becoming less and less useful for academic analysis To be fair, the OECD (2003) came - rightly to place greater emphasis on the knowledge-intensity of industries. Measuring the direct plus indirect technology content of particular industries.

  5. What is a LMT Sector and what innovation in it? Appraising innovation through adopting conventional sectoral classifications can be misleading. Innovation is rapid in particular segments of both high-tech and LMT sectors, (even if more segments of the high-tech sectors display such rapid innovation) It is possible to detach the high-tech segments from LMT industries : e.g. Artificial fibers in textiles when they arose to compete with natural fibers but the final products remain very similar, so this looks specious . .

  6. What are we talking about? Conventionally, sectors of all types were supposed to be different not only in the goods and services but also in the technologies and processes they used to produce them. However The boundaries have blurred over historical time in both dimensions . Technologies originally developed for one set of products spill over into use in the production or architecture of other sets of products. new technologies more often tend to supplement and complement old technologies rather than replace them. even old products can be produced by elements drawn from what had previously been a totally different set of activities (e.g. synthetic fibers in textiles). bundling of goods and services (music on internet)

  7. Innovation drivers in LMT industries 1) The demand The drivers of change as they affect low, medium, and high-tech sectors can be similarly envisaged from the side: 1. of the products (and the demand!) 2. or from the side of the technologies significant differences in interpretation and understanding. Firms hold different interpretative frames , and drivers are particularly important because their well-established markets, necessitate a broader variety of strategic choices for differentiation. Demands change sometimes slowly but sometimes rapidly and unpredictably, negating attempts to routinize operations and generating turbulence.

  8. A) Demand differentiation: 1) quality innovation and 2) new tastes 1) Quality innovation a) New markets Even older industries can bounce back, by producing for new markets. The same type of goods for untouched regions can work for well-known brands (Coca-Cola) but producing different types of the same categories of good ( product differentiation ) is generally necessary for such resurgence. Low-tech industries face somewhat inelastic demands (many produce comparative necessities, and as consumers attain higher income levels, they have satisfed most of their needs for necessities).

  9. b) New scope for new products (also through technolgy) To stave off this satiation of wants, producers in LMT industries have to find new products to attract the custom of higher earners. The availability of advanced technologies may be an important factor for innovation strategies in LMT firms through dictating the scope for such new products. Even then may not result in products that customers find attractive, as has been the case for genetically modified foodstuffs in some countries. In addition to quality upgrading, consumers may switch their demand patterns to goods which have new characteristics. E.g. Auto/food/Energy: intense pressure from communities and from governments to produce safer and more environmentally friendly items. Adding value in processing (e.g. sensors in tires) Shifts in product mixes to reflect the changing composition of consumers, for example the implications of demographic change (gender relations, ageing, etc.).

  10. What defininition to be used? Approaches (= classification; taxonomy, etc.) that blend the technology dimension and the product dimension, appear to be: more analytically satisfying better able to account for observed empirical differences between countries and regions better able to account for dynamic paths of industrial evolution over historical time. They need however to be supplemented by technology-oriented distinctions among sectors (e.g. Pavitt taxonomy) to provide a better grasp of the nature of structural change and competitiveness. Furthermore, they are in our view a more advisable platform for policy than simple OECD-style definitions of high- or low-tech.

  11. Some problems in defining technology! The majority of manufacturing industries are defined mostly according to their product range but a good number have in common their technologies rather than their products, E.g. biotechnology. - plant biotechnology is regarded as part of the biotechnology industry (technology-defined) or of agriculture (product- defined) makes a big difference to the inferences drawn. Moreover innovation activities in LMT tend to fall outside conventional definition of R&D activities (es. OECD Frascati Manual)

  12. Innovation drivers in LMT industries 2) New Technological Paradigms a) General Purpose Technologies and Learning in LMT Firms Key technologies often have the property of being able to become pervasive (they can spill out of their industry of origin and be recruited by older industries) Machinery, steam power, and iron (I Industrial Revolution) information and communication technologies, biotechnology and smart materials in the III IR (= General Purpose Technologies). III created new opportunities for LMT industries to enhance their innovative and economic performance through new technologies However, in LMT industries there is usually little formal learning by science and technology, at least at the firm level (innovation and adoption operate in practical and pragmatic ways by doing and using)

  13. The absorptive capacity and the R&D function The bulk of the general-purpose technologies, are developed by separate companies (rarely subsidiaries), specialized in the relevant technological fields. However the downstream LMT industries need to have absorptive capacities to make productive use of these upstream developments. food-processing companies involved in advanced ( third-generation ) biotechnology do not carry out much of the associated research themselves but are often prominent in patenting in less advanced ( second-generation ) biotechnology this seems to provide them with the necessary absorptive capabilities. Formal science may congregate in national or regional laboratories in such industries, instead of being internalized within firms Innovation require firm-speciWc absorptive capacities, generated not just from formal R&D but from broader-based innovative activities that include engineering, continuous improvement processes, and organizational innovations such as integrated service and supply.

  14. Carrier Industries (general purpose techn.) Describing one particular industry supplying technologies, namely machine tools, Rosenberg (1963) showed how the number of different types of tools was quite limited and as a result their principles could readily be stretched to being applied in industries other than where they were first deployed. Signifcant role of carrier industries, which incorporated these proliferating machine tools into making the machines they produced or used (producing machines related to those tools ). general purpose technologies : any industry can act as a carrier if its demand for the new capital good is large enough or growing fast enough. Thus even low-tech sectors can act as receptors for new process-oriented technologies (e.g. machine tools for 3d printers).

  15. Research in LMT industries. Knowledge search, identification and proof, rather than basic research, are likely to be of particular importance to innovation in the non-manufacturing activities of LMT industries. We have to ask what part of each industry we are characterizing as high- or low-tech when considering their growth potential advantage In low-growth sectors (such as processed foods) innovation lies towards the high-tech end of these low-growth sectors (like applying biotechnology to food processing).

  16. More useful (complex) taxonomies 1) Peneder Peneder (2001): tripartite classification (but starting form Product ) 1. one of his taxonomies rests on factor intensity (mainstream i.e. average; labor-intensive; capital-intensive; marketing-driven; technology-intensive), 2. another on labour skills (low-skill; medium-skill blue-collar; medium-skill white-collar; high-skill), 3. and the third on external service inputs (from knowledge-based services; from retail and advertising services; from transport services; and from other industries).

  17. 1b) Peneder Taxonomy Only one of the ninety-nine manufacturing industries Peneder lists ( aircraft and spacecraft ) has the classic high-tech profile of being: technology-intensive and predominantly using high-skill and knowledge-based services! Conversely, there are labor-intensive industries which utilize high skills (e.g. machine tools) and others utilizing knowledge-based service inputs (some branches of metallurgy). His classification underlines the great variety of observable combinations.

  18. 2) The Pavit Taxonomy (1984) of sectoral innovation patterns (see also chaptera on SIS) Pavitt (1984) proposes four types of sectoral pattern for innovative activities. I. In supplier-dominated (e.g. textile, services) sectors, new technologies are embodied in new components and equipment, and the diffusion of new technologies and learning takes place through learning-by-doing and by-using. II. In scale-intensive sectors (e.g. autos, steel), process innovation is relevant and the sources of innovation are both internal (R&D and learning-by-doing) and external (equipment producers), while appropriability is obtained through secrecy and patents. III. In specialized suppliers (e.g. equipment producers), innovation is focused on performance improvement, reliability, and customization, with the sources of innovation being both internal (tacit knowledge and experience of skilled technicians) and external (user producer interaction); appropriability comes mainly from the localized and interactive nature of knowledge. IV. Finally, science-based sectors (e.g. pharmaceuticals, electronics) are characterized by a high rate of product and process innovations, by internal R&D, and by scientifc research done at universities and public research laboratories; science is a source of innovation, and appropriability means are of various types, ranging from patents, to lead-times and learning curves,

  19. Difficulties in classifying LMT! Pavitt (and others, as Marsili) deliberately aimed at means of classification that brought together characteristics which certain groups of technologies appeared to share, even though they might pertain to different sectors. Generally this taxonomies do a better job of explaining technological performance than factor content ..However, again, the LMT industries resist easy classification, precisely because many of them are not very distinctive or singular in technological terms. For instance: growing export industries sprinkled all first four categories of Pavitt taxonomy!

  20. 3) The Sutton taxonomy: relationships with the industry/market structure Sutton: firms are prepared to spend on marketing their products on the one hand, and on developing their technologies on the other (trad-off) It depends on factors that were partly under a firm s control and partly beyond it! Sutton approach and associated taxonomy can be especially useful for analyzing LMT industries, because supply (technology) is combined with demand (product) aspects in a rigorous way.

  21. E.g. The tire industry E.g. Tire industry - Sunk costs; heavy market concentration; Capital intensive; large scale; not strong changes in basic technology (rubber) Global Oligopolistic structure! Technology is applied by the tire manufacturers to reduce costs, to differentiate the product line and to focus on greater value-adding activities (Acha and Brusoni 2003). Complexity in the nature of Knowledge Basis; Interface between chemical knowledge base (rubber) and others (sensors, electronics, car engineering, etc.) Facing a global market where it is more and more difficult to make a profit, the leading manufacturers are continuously focusing on reducing costs through reducing throughput and labor costs (including the long-awaited introduction of robotics), innovations in processing technologies and source product (a new polyurethane tire polymer), and in the method itself (e.g. sensors in tires). Beyond influencing the cost and ease of production, tire manufacturers have invested in research and technology to also help them to move away from the commodity trap, where products can only compete on price. (e.g. also marketing: colored tires!). Or moving up the value chain by manufacturing entire tire assembly systems. High-tech providers; Patents; High R&D rates

  22. Fi r m s a n d Co r p o r a t e Fi r m s a n d Co r p o r a t e Ch i i n L M T In d u s t r n L M T In d u s t r i i e s = Issues concerning strategies and structures at the firm level (economies of scale and scope; vert./horiz. Integration) in both large firms and SMEs: relations with technologies and innovation processes Ch a n g e a n g e e s STRATEGIES A) orthodox vision Porter (1985) : three main types of corporate strategy, namely: a) cost leadership, b) differentiation; c) focus. cost leadership is the likely choice of firms in a mature LMT industry (process innovation only to pare down costs even) . B) Alternative points of view: technology related also to . Branding (product reputation) is often crucial to the choice of a differentiation strategy (e.g. Skoda is nowadays using advertising of its new technologies to change deep-seated customer prejudices); Focus in terms of multidivisional firm (many focused markets): it may rise several problems (if there are spillovers between the same functions located in different divisions)

  23. Why Porter approach is not valid in interpreeting the technology issue in LMT industries? In contrast to the orthodox vision (Porter), in practice, managers consider particular activities rather than the whole ( corporate strategy ) at once. A technology frame (and not a pure strategic frame), therefore, is the actual interpretative system of managers to understand the firm technological position and innovation opportunities! Oil and Gas industry: there is little direct correlation between formal technological performance (say patenting and scientific publications) and business performance (say expansion or profitability), unless this intervening variable of the frame is accounted for by managers!

  24. The technology frame concept The frame concept is relevant to the study of innovation in LMTsectors. Firms in LMT industries are basically using rather than selling technology, and therefore tend to adopt technology frames that are: a) quite different from those in high-tech industries (where technology itself is a key selling point), b) and often quite different from other LMT firms even in the same industry. In general, the market characteristics of LMT industries (segmentation, differentiation, etc.) lead firms to different interpretations about the role for technology for commercial success. In high-tech firms, by contrast, the role for technology is more central to commercial success, and there may be greater tendencies for consensus (general or by groups) on aspects of technology frames across these competing firms variation in technology frames across high-tech firms derives more from a focus on how the technology (broadly stated) should develop, whereas variation in technology frames amongst LMT firms pertains more to what the role for technology (broadly stated) should be.

  25. Scale and Scope in LMT industries and technology: Large Firms and SMEs Some mature LMT industries (as meatpacking, automobile production, and consumer durables, etc.) were important sources of production innovation in their early years It is (partially) true that driving force of mass production was to reap economies of scale in the production processes, and the M-form (multidivisional) company was a very suitable organizational form for doing so However, time-saving was a very relevant way to get economies: this was achieved through raising throughput, reducing downtime, and improving the machinery Dynamic economies of scale, not usual static scale economies arising, for instance, out of having large plant!

  26. New ways to get dynamic economies of scale LARGE COMPANIES decline in average establishment size ( minimills ) system of lean production (e.g. Toyota) - which was a response to the needs of customers for variety and specialization while sacrificing as little as possible of the benefits of high throughput; Just in time, etc. dynamic economies of scope to balance loss of standardization; Long run conversion process, but innovation and technology often related to those targets!

  27. SMEs innovation potential (in LMT industries) Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) have reappeared on government technology policy agendas. Renewed emphasis as possible sources of innovation (perceived advantage of SMEs in responding quickly to technological change, because of the absence of complex management structures within smaller enterprises). Against that, SMEs may lack the financial power to undertake the kinds of investments in new technologies Questions of access to new technologies and on what terms; they are often (perhaps unfairly) seen as a matter for despair in LMT sectors.;

  28. Vertical and horizontal integration The LMT industries have been characterized by a variety of patterns of vertical integration and disintegration through their development across time. 1. At the beginning, high degree of vertical stratification (not integration) - segments interact in systemic fashion with one another through the vertical chains. imbalances in development affecting the value chain . 2. In the second phase of industrialization there were pressures to link the segmented processes (vertical integration. The pressures of throughput that gave rise to mass production ; smooth production flows throughout the value chain). 3. More recently, the rise of the steel minimill , partly from technical change, at the expense of the large integrated mill has been one of the more dramatic demonstrations of a retreat from vertical integration (see before).

  29. Recent trends at firm level Tasks previously undertook have been outsourced , thereby returning to the traditional low-tech model of vertical disintegration even in some high-tech industries. To retain and intensify the economies of scope required in this unfolding set of circumstances, companies also chose to limit the range of their horizontal diversification. downsizing and in many cases stripped out large numbers of middle management in the belief that this furthered lean production. While financial considerations had often encouraged diversification into unrelated activities, studies demonstrated that conglomerate firms based on unrelated diversification were not very profitable.. Taking on board the technological and production aspects, and thereby taking into account the issues of synergies and economies of scope, many firms reoriented their structure to limit themselves to related diversification. Yet many of the larger companies in low-tech industries like food manufacturing continue to pursue apparently unrelated diversification: low technological opportunity in traditional segments of low-tech industries may also go with relatively high appropriability, especially through branding (rather than through technology!)

  30. Dynamic changes at industry level: Vertical Alignment and Networks Changes at the firm level in terms of size, integration and diversification carry strong implications for the structure of the industries. To overcome hierarchical control, firms have been driven to develop closer relationships with upstream suppliers and downstream customers. Toyota system: high reliance on suppliers to deliver on time and of high quality; joint development with the supplier; long periods of time negotiating the exact specifications and costings; first-tier (or second tier, etc.) suppliers worked in close association with Toyota wherever the production was located, as Systems integrators hat is, Each integrator would be surrounded by a network of suppliers and related activities. New power balance emerge; In the lower-tech industries especially, like textiles and some branches of food, the manufacturing stages of the chain were squeezed as power tended to shift downstream to the final stages and even to the retailers.

  31. Industrial patterns How do industries differ in their behavior?; Can one observe different patterns in LMT industries than high-tech industries at the industry and sector levels? Are the Schumpeter Marks relevant and useful? What results if you adopt the SIS approach (Malerba)? key conditions: opportunity, appropriability, cumulativeness, and knowledge base). Clothing falls o into the category of Mark I, characterized by low technological opportunity, weak appropriability of any innovations, small firms and rapid entry and exit, practical rather than scientific knowledge base. Motor vehicles as a medium-tech industry have greater technological opportunities, greater appropriability and the persistence (cumulativness) of large firms.

  32. Technological opportunities and outsourcing Some of the lowtech industries are Mark I but others are nearer to Mark II, while food-processing resists any easy classification since its sub-branches operate in a whole variety of ways. Where demand plays such a large role, market opportunity can be as important as technological opportunity, and may be very diVerent in extent as well as in nature. Fast-growing areas of consumption are not always the same as fast-growing areas of technology, as noted above. However, technological opportunities may be enlarging again for low- tech industries, although firms will for the most part outsource the development of these new technologies. Outsourcing may limit opportunities for user firms to appropriate the returns from innovation that relies on this approach

  33. LMT and appropriability within the supply chain In the supplier-dominated low-tech industries (as defined by Pavitt) the appropriability of technologies rests upon the division of power between the technology developers the upstream suppliers and the users, like food or clothing companies. These activities are rarely vertically integrated, because the suppliers usually wish to supply a variety of users both within the same activity and outside. The appropriability of the products depends on both the marketing endeavours of the companies concerned, and the power balance vis-a`- vis downstream distributors and retailers. Links with technology suppliers tend to be much more distant than in high- tech sectors.

  34. Techn. accumulation: entries and exits Many LMT industries are characterized by high levels of turbulence, with a churning of entry and exit. These pose the issue of learning in turbulent environments if new entrants may simply replicate their predecessors mistakes! In North American environments at least, the individuals concerned do tend to go on to form another firm Alternatively the continuity can be maintained by technological dependence on a large supplier or an industrial district (e.g. clothing.) In complex products systems, where alliances are reconstituted for each new project, learning is achieved by the flux of interactions of the constituent firms, although a high level of forgetting also seems to be common..

  35. Final message The dichotomous Mark I and II categorizations may be too restrictive to portray the main patterns of evolution of diVerent industries, and more complex schema such as that of Pavitt (1984) or Malerba may be preferable for understanding the impact of differing technologies.

  36. Dynemic Competition in time Across the full range of industries, the modern era is supposed to be characterized by competition that has intensified because of globalization and because of more rapid change in market demand. In LMT industries the pace of change and competition may be less intense, as market leaders seek to retain their predominance by brand loyalty. Marketing-based appropriability offsets some of the pressures to develop new products. However frms in LMT industries are also susceptible to innovations that accelerate the development times ( cycle time ) and rate of application and diffusion for new technologies (e.g. ICT for customer service)

  37. Governamental Policies: Government technology policies at national and supranational levels have on the whole tended to give the highest priority to high-tech sectors and activities (benchmark = share of HT activities). Such a benchmark falls into the trap of confusing the sector with the technology level. Traditional innovation policy: linear model of technology-push . Although this approach does not preclude applications of high technology to more traditional fields, in fact focus is on new sectors On the other side, for many decades the bias towards such technologies was also coupled to one towards consolidation of (LMT) firms and industries, seen as national champions for technological and commercial success. In recent times, SMEs have been increasingly thought of as progenitors of high technology, in fields such as biotechnology and genomics, software, advanced instrumentation, and so on. Yet in low-tech industries, SMEs are most widely seen as dragging down overall performance.

  38. Rebalancing The antithesis of the supply push contribution of the linear model is the demand pull approach to innovation, in which the causal sequence is reversed. Governments, though, tend to be loath to leave it all to market forces, in an arena in which market failures are so evidently present as they are in innovative activities. While this may not overcome all the market failure shortcomings, there there is room for rebalancing policy in such a way as to place greater stress on the Technology diffusion aspects. diffusion of high-tech activities into supposedly low-tech sectors: there is a much wider scope for such migration of technologies across sectoral boundaries than is often supposed.

  39. Locked countries A perhaps even larger number of countries have become locked into the low-tech activities and never adequately escaped, as is often alleged for Latin America. The difficulty remains that countries comparative advantages often remain indissolubly linked to the low-tech sectors. Key message: there are no true low-tech sectors in the modern world however overrides this. It is perfectly possible to diffuse high technologies into the low-tech sectors In that way, intermediate and developing countries do not need to face a dilemma when choosing between: static comparative advantage in traditional fields and dynamic comparative advantage from technological opportunity! Opportunities from: downstreaming diffusion of high-tech activities into low-tech sectors, and from the lateral diffusion of old technological Welds into new ones.

  40. Countries like Switzerland developed, consciously or unconsciously, a pattern of evolution that went in this case from textiles to dyeing and chemicals and then into strength in pharmaceuticals on the one hand, and into machinery and thence to advanced engineering on the other. A clear implication of these policy considerations is that strength in low- tech sectors does not have to act as a block to development, although national and supranational governments frequently embody this error in their technology policies. The block to development view can be replaced by a development block view, in which LMT sectors act as carrier industries for diffusing the gains from new technologies across the industrial spectrum, as they have so often managed to do in the past

Related


More Related Content

giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#