Impact of Negative Nominal Interest Rates on Bank Performance

Why Have Negative Nominal Interest Rates Had
Such a Small Effect on Bank Performance?  Cross
Country Evidence
Jose A. Lopez, Andrew K. Rose, and Mark M. Spiegel*
Bank for International Settlements
July 6, 2018
*Comments are my own and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors or
the FRBSF
L
o
w
 
i
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
r
a
t
e
s
 
c
o
n
c
e
r
n
 
f
o
r
 
b
a
n
k
s
Following financial crisis, rates reduced towards “zero lower
bound” (ZLB)
Potential obstacle to bank profitability
Nominal deposit rates could not be reduced below zero without
eroding banks’ customer base.
Low interest rates reduce bank profitability [Jobst and Lin (2016)].
Concern confirmed empirically
 Borio, et al (2017) bank profitability reduced at low rates of interest
 Borio and Gambacorta (2017) bank lending less responsive to
policy rates around ZLB, weakening transmission mechanism
E
v
e
n
 
w
o
r
s
e
 
a
t
 
n
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
r
a
t
e
s
Adjustments in deposit rates likely to hit a hard stop at the
zero bound.
Banks generally unwilling to charge negative nominal interest rates
on deposits, especially for smaller customers
Eggertson, et al (2017): Negative rates disrupt monetary
transmission
Evidence from aggregate data from five countries and the euro area
as well as bank-level data from Sweden.
Rostagno, et al (2016): movements into negative rates may
induce lending by increasing cost of hoarding cash
M
a
n
y
 
i
n
d
i
v
i
d
u
a
l
 
c
u
r
r
e
n
c
y
 
s
t
u
d
i
e
s
 
o
f
 
n
e
g
t
i
v
e
 
r
a
t
e
s
Bank-level studies
Most conclude that responses at bank level mitigated adverse
effect of negative rates on bank profitability and lending
Increasing non-interest income (such as increased fees)
Adjust funding allocations to rely less on deposits
Adjustments depend on both bank business model and size,
as both influence reliance on deposit funding
However, move to negative rates likely reflects fundamentals
Leaves it difficult to identify changes in bank profitability solely from
negative rates.
R
e
l
e
v
a
n
t
 
l
i
t
e
r
a
t
u
r
e
Studies under low positive rates
Borio, et al (2017), Borio and Gambacorta (2017), Delis and
Kouretas (2011), Bikker and Vervliet (2017)
Economies under negative nominal interest rates
Bech and Malkhozov (2016):
4 CBs in Europe since 2014
Negative rates similar to low positive rates
Turk (2016): Danish and Swedish bank margins roughly stable
across the zero threshold
M
i
c
r
o
 
d
a
t
a
 
n
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
r
a
t
e
 
s
t
u
d
i
e
s
 
f
o
r
 
i
n
d
i
v
i
d
u
a
l
c
u
r
r
e
n
c
i
e
s
Heider, et al (2017): 46 eurozone banks 2013-2015
Negative rates in euro area induced deposit-dependent banks to cut
lending, and reallocate loans towards more risky firms.
Nucera, et al (2017): 111 eurozone banks
Negative rates induced smaller banks to increase riskiness
Basten and Mariathasan (2018): 68 Swiss banks
Banks with higher excess reserves raised fees and interest income
to compensate for negative liability margins
Demiralp, et al (2017): 205 euro area banks
HD banks extend more loans under negative rates than LD
M
u
l
t
i
-
c
u
r
r
e
n
c
y
 
p
a
n
e
l
 
a
l
l
o
w
s
 
f
o
r
 
g
l
o
b
a
l
 
s
h
o
c
k
s
Different economies move to negative rates at different times
Include fixed time effects to control for global conditions
Global shocks particularly relevant over sample period [Rey (2015)]
Some countries in sample never experience negative rates
Can be viewed as a difference-in-difference study
Compare banks in economies that experienced negative rates,
before and after policy rates turned negative
Local conditions also likely affect both bank profitability and
monetary policy
Respond by instrumenting proxies for local conditions
F
i
r
s
t
 
s
t
u
d
y
 
p
o
o
l
i
n
g
 
E
u
r
o
p
e
a
n
 
a
n
d
 
J
a
p
a
n
e
s
e
 
b
a
n
k
s
 
u
n
d
e
r
n
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
r
a
t
e
s
Annual income statements for 5,113 banks from 2010-2016
14 different currencies, one of which is the 19 country euro
Countries “go negative” at different times for different reasons
Example: Movements into negative rates different in floating and
pegged exchange rate countries
Latter respond more to pressures that might undermine the peg.
Sample also includes large number of banks
Allows analysis of banks most exposed to negative interest rates
Split data into sub-samples by: a) bank size, and b) reliance on
deposits.
R
e
s
u
l
t
s
:
 
B
a
n
k
 
p
r
o
f
i
t
a
b
i
l
i
t
y
 
u
n
a
f
f
e
c
t
e
d
 
b
y
 
n
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
n
o
m
i
n
a
l
 
i
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
r
a
t
e
s
No substantive effect on net income from negative rates.
ssssNotable because sample includes relatively large share of small
and high-deposit banks
Both expected to be more exposed to negative rate losses
Do find statistically significant losses in net interest income
Statistically significant losses both on lending income and “other”
interest income
Mitigated by reductions in interest expenses, but not sufficiently
Notably, banks do not substantially reduce deposit expenses
Heterogeneity: Large banks do achieve reduction in deposit
expenses, small banks don’t
L
o
s
s
e
s
 
o
n
 
n
e
t
 
i
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
i
n
c
o
m
e
 
m
a
d
e
 
u
p
 
o
n
 
n
o
n
-
i
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
i
n
c
o
m
e
Significant gains in net non-interest income
Increases in fees
Increases in other non-interest income (capital gains, gains on
securities, insurance)
Differences by bank type
Large banks also reduce other interest expenses more than their
smaller counterparts.
Low-deposit (LD) banks do better under negative interest rates than
high-deposit (HD) counterparts
LD banks actually suffer bigger reductions in net interest income, but also
achieve larger increases in net non-interest income
D
a
t
a
Fitch Global Banking database
Balance sheet and income statement variables for individual banks,
2010-2016
28 European countries and Japan
Variety of monetary regimes, including monetary unions, exchange
rate peggers, and inflation targeters
Data begins 2 years before negative nominal interest rates
Includes all negative nominal interest rate countries through 2016
D
i
f
f
e
r
e
n
c
e
 
f
r
o
m
 
t
h
e
 
e
x
i
s
t
i
n
g
 
l
i
t
e
r
a
t
u
r
e
Variety of countries with different monetary regimes
Enter negative rates at different points in time, if at all.
Five economies experienced negative nominal policy interest
rates: Denmark, EMU, Japan, Sweden, and Switzerland
Denmark first into negative rates July 2012
Swiss interest rates most negative (on sight deposit rates at -0.75%)
Similar countries that did not go negative
Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Hungary, and the UK
Allows time fixed effects to account for global conditions
More generally, difference-in-differences strategy, since not all
experienced negative rates, and none for the entire sample.
The second difference from the literature is that, with over
5,100 banks and more than 30,00 observations, our data set is
relatively large.  The database allows us to examine closely
the effects of negative rates on banks that differ along several
dimensions, such as size and deposit-reliance.  We identify a
bank as large if its assets exceed $10 billion during the
sample; about an eighth of our banks are large.  Similarly, we
define a bank as high-deposit if its deposits exceeded 75% of
total funding at some point in the sample, as is true of four-
fifths of our sample.
Our data set has a few complications.  One is that banks
report information using different (sometimes multiple)
accounting methods.  While we used bank-level fixed effects
throughout, we are interested in using as consistent a sample
as possible.  Towards that end, when we have duplicate time
series of banks reported in different accounting methods, we
drop the less-popularly-used method for the bank’s country.
We also drop banks that use accounting systems
unconventional for their own country.   Finally, we generally
choose unconsolidated observations, only reporting
consolidated observations if unconsolidated are unavailable.
Our annual observations are typically reported in the fourth
quarter, though our Japanese banks report them in the first
quarter.  Since our data set also has suspicious outliers, we
typically truncate variables at the first and ninety-ninth
percentiles, dropping the outliers (a few exceptions to this rule
are tabulated below).
Descriptive statistics for our data set are tabulated in Appendix
Table A1.  At the right of the table, we present mean values for
bank income (measured as a percentage of total assets),
along with standard deviations.  These are presented for nine
different monetary regimes, in rows.  We compare bank
profitability under negative and low positive nominal interest
rates, defining the latter as a policy rate that is within the [0,
1%) range (hereafter we refer to “positive” rather than “low
positive” rates, for the sake of brevity).   Of the five economies
that experienced negative nominal interest rates, net income
was, on average, higher under positive rates for the EMU,
Japan, and Sweden.  However, the differences between
positive and negative rates were small, and both Danish and
Swiss banks did slightly better with negative rates.  This
impression is corroborated by Figure 1, which scatters bank
profitability against the policy rate.  The fitted regression line
has essentially no slope, suggesting little effect of interest
rates on bank profitability.
D
a
t
a
 
s
e
t
 
i
s
 
l
a
r
g
e
Over 5,100 banks and more than 30,00 observations
Allows examination of effects of negative rates on banks that
differ by size and deposit-reliance
Identify large as assets exceed $10 billion (1/8 of sample)
Define HD as deposits exceeded 75% of funding (4/5 of sample)
Complications
Multiple accounting methods
Generally choose unconsolidated observations
Japanese banks report in first quarter
Truncate outliers at 1% and 99%
L
o
s
s
e
s
 
o
n
 
n
e
t
 
i
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
i
n
c
o
m
e
 
m
a
d
e
 
u
p
 
o
n
 
n
o
n
-
i
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
i
n
c
o
m
e
Significant gains in net non-interest income
Increases in fees
Increases in other non-interest income (capital gains, gains on
securities, insurance)
Differences by bank type
Large banks also reduce other interest expenses more than their
smaller counterparts.
Low-deposit (LD) banks do better under negative interest rates than
high-deposit (HD) counterparts
LD banks actually suffer bigger reductions in net interest income, but also
achieve larger increases in net non-interest income
L
i
t
t
l
e
 
o
v
e
r
a
l
l
 
d
i
f
f
e
r
e
n
c
e
 
i
n
 
p
r
o
f
i
t
a
b
i
l
i
t
y
 
a
c
r
o
s
s
 
Z
L
B
D
e
s
c
r
i
p
t
i
v
e
 
S
t
a
t
i
s
t
i
c
s
N
o
 
a
p
p
a
r
e
n
t
 
d
i
f
f
e
r
e
n
c
e
s
 
i
n
 
r
a
w
 
d
a
t
a
F
i
g
u
r
e
 
1
:
 
B
a
n
k
 
p
r
o
f
i
t
a
b
i
l
i
t
y
 
u
n
d
e
r
 
p
o
s
i
t
i
v
e
 
a
n
d
 
n
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
p
o
l
i
c
y
 
r
a
t
e
s
B
a
s
e
 
s
p
e
c
i
f
i
c
a
t
i
o
n
Conventional least-squares panel specification:
  
  
Y
ijt
 = βNEGI
jt
 + {δ
i
} + {θ
t
} + ε
ijt
     
(1)
where:
Y
ijt
 is dependent variable for bank i in economy j for year t
NEGI
jt
 is 1 if country j had a negative nominal policy interest rate during
year t, and 0 otherwise (nominal rates>1 are dropped)
{δ} and {θ} are comprehensive sets of bank- and time-specific fixed
effects
ε represents a residual, assumed to be well-behaved
B
a
s
e
 
s
p
e
c
i
f
i
c
a
t
i
o
n
 
(
2
)
Coefficient of interest is β
Average effect of negative nominal interest rates
Use robust standard errors, clustered by bank.
Consider number of measures of bank performance
Calculated as ratios of total assets
Drop outliers, observations outside (1,99) percentiles
Confirm results insensitive to the use of earning assets instead
of total
Exclude values of net income (to total assets) greater than
20% in absolute value
B
a
s
e
 
s
p
e
c
i
f
i
c
a
t
i
o
n
 
r
e
s
u
l
t
s
N
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
N
o
m
i
n
a
l
 
I
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
R
a
t
e
s
 
a
n
d
 
B
a
n
k
 
P
r
o
f
i
t
a
b
i
l
i
t
y
B
a
s
e
 
r
e
s
u
l
t
s
 
i
n
d
i
c
a
t
e
 
s
m
a
l
l
 
n
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
r
a
t
e
 
i
m
p
a
c
t
Economically small – but positive – and statistically
insignificant effect on bank net income, compared with low
positive rates
Masks large movements in income components
Net interest income falls significantly by around 5.4 bp
Almost precisely offset by gains in net non-interest income of 5.2 bp.
Offsetting results suggest banks are reluctant to charge their
depositors negative rates
Results in losses from interest income
Compensate for losses with gains from non-interest income
R
e
s
u
l
t
s
 
r
o
b
u
s
t
 
t
o
 
v
a
r
i
e
t
y
 
o
f
 
p
e
r
t
u
r
b
a
t
i
o
n
s
S
e
n
s
i
t
i
v
i
t
y
 
A
n
a
l
y
s
i
s
D
e
c
o
m
p
o
s
i
t
i
o
n
 
o
f
 
n
e
t
 
i
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
i
n
c
o
m
e
N
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
N
o
m
i
n
a
l
 
I
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
R
a
t
e
s
 
a
n
d
 
B
a
n
k
 
I
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
I
n
c
o
m
e
 
a
n
d
 
E
x
p
e
n
s
e
s
I
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
e
x
p
e
n
s
e
 
c
u
t
s
 
l
e
s
s
 
t
h
a
n
 
r
e
v
e
n
u
e
 
l
o
s
s
e
s
Both gross interest income and expense show economically
significant and statistically significant declines
Decline in expenses is smaller
Decline in gross interest income largest for loan income
Other interest income decline also significant
Customer deposits insignificant
Matches conventional wisdom
Banks suffer interest losses but can’t pass fully on to depositors
Hence, bank net interest income declines
D
i
f
f
e
r
e
n
c
e
s
 
a
c
r
o
s
s
 
b
a
n
k
s
Large banks seem more nimble than smaller banks
Suffer smaller and insignificant declines in gross interest income
Also cut expenses further, avoiding losses on net income
 LD banks suffer significantly greater losses in gross interest
income, especially income from loans
To offset losses, LD and HD banks lower interest expenses
However, LD banks lower “other interest expenses” more
More reliant on other, market-based funding sources
Differences in deposit expenses much smaller
D
e
c
o
m
p
o
s
i
t
i
o
n
 
o
f
 
n
o
n
-
i
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
i
n
c
o
m
e
N
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
N
o
m
i
n
a
l
 
I
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
R
a
t
e
s
 
a
n
d
 
B
a
n
k
 
N
o
n
-
I
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
I
n
c
o
m
e
 
a
n
d
 
E
x
p
e
n
s
e
s
I
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
e
x
p
e
n
s
e
 
c
u
t
s
 
l
e
s
s
 
t
h
a
n
 
r
e
v
e
n
u
e
 
l
o
s
s
e
s
Increase in net non-interest income stems from an increase in
gross income, rather than a decline in expenses
Two sources increasing gross income, both significant:
Increase in net fees
Improvements in other types of non-interest income, such as capital
gains and gains on securities and insurance
 But change in most non-interest expenses insignificant
Exception is “other non-interest expenses,” including capital gains on
securities and interest expenses, which increase
D
i
f
f
e
r
e
n
c
e
s
 
a
c
r
o
s
s
 
b
a
n
k
s
Few substantive differences between large and small banks
Relatively large discrepancies across HD and LD banks
Modest differences in point estimates for non-interest expenses
Increase in gross non-interest income for LD banks about 10 times
size of that enjoyed by HD banks
Most from increases in non-fee income, which may reflect gains on securities
May be associated with unanticipated movements into negative rates
Benign impact of negative rates might in part reflect immediate
capital gains on bond holdings for LD banks
However, remaining under negative rates may not be painless
Medium-tern impacts of negative rates may differ
D
i
f
f
e
r
e
n
c
e
s
 
a
c
r
o
s
s
 
m
o
n
e
t
a
r
y
 
r
e
g
i
m
e
s
Data includes three different types of monetary regimes
Large number members of EMU, (3 Baltic countries joined)
Largest negative rate monetary regime
Floating exchange rates
Japan, Sweden and Switzerland (but not Czech Republic, Hungary or the
UK) experienced negative nominal interest rates.
Fixed exchange rates
Bulgaria and Denmark (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania prior to EMU entry)
Only Denmark experienced negative interest rates.
Analysis implicitly exploits this panel variation
Next, reexamine results by  monetary regime
R
e
s
u
l
t
s
 
f
o
r
 
d
i
f
f
e
r
e
n
t
 
m
o
n
e
t
a
r
y
 
r
e
g
i
m
e
s
T
a
b
l
e
 
4
:
 
N
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
N
o
m
i
n
a
l
 
I
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
R
a
t
e
s
 
E
f
f
e
c
t
s
 
A
c
r
o
s
s
 
E
c
o
n
o
m
i
e
s
R
e
s
u
l
t
s
 
i
n
d
i
c
a
t
e
 
i
m
p
o
r
t
a
n
c
e
 
o
f
 
p
a
n
e
l
 
a
p
p
r
o
c
h
Results for Japan and Germany erroneously negative
Unable to control for time fixed effects; interpret with caution
Demonstrates advantage of cross-country panel
Literature often uses banks from single monetary regime
Other samples more credible
Countries with exchange rates pegged to the Euro
European countries that maintained flexible exchange rates
Flexers plus Eurozone
All economies with flexible exchange rates 
 
M
u
c
h
 
h
e
t
e
r
o
g
e
n
e
i
t
y
 
a
c
r
o
s
s
 
m
o
n
e
t
a
r
y
 
r
e
g
i
m
e
 
p
a
n
e
l
s
None of the five panel estimates indicate significant effect of
negative nominal interest rates on bank profitability
Stark contrast with national results indicating significant decline in
bank profits in both Japan and Germany
Decomposition of sub-panels consistent with full sample
Observed significant effect on net interest income always negative
Significant coefficients for net non-interest income positive
Result that negative rates only have a small overall effect
appears driven by floating exchange rate economies
C
o
n
c
l
u
s
i
o
n
 
(
1
)
Examine banks under negative nominal interest rates
First study under negative rates for different monetary regimes
Panel allows conditioning for global shocks, and dis-aggregating by
both size and dependence on deposit-funding
Find little overall impact on bank profitability, compared with
low positive rates
Components of income respond significantly
Decline in net interest income
Largely offset by increases in non-interest income
Results driven by countries with floating exchange rates, and
small or LD banks
 
Overall, our results suggest that banks fare relatively well
under negative nominal interest rates, compared to low
positive rates.  The considerable heterogeneity we find makes
us cautious to conclude that the financial channel of the
monetary transmission mechanism remains unchanged as
policy rates cross zero.  That is especially true since the
positive returns in “other non-interest income” enjoyed by
banks under negative rates may well be unsustainable if they
are driven by the capital gains stemming from negative
interest rate surprises.
C
o
n
c
l
u
s
i
o
n
 
(
2
)
Overall, results suggest banks fare relatively well under
negative nominal rates, compared to low positive
Considerable heterogeneity raises caution in concluding that
monetary transmission mechanism unchanged
Particularly since positive returns in “other non-interest
income” may be unsustainable over medium term
Capital gains from negative interest rate surprises unlikely to persist
R
e
s
u
l
t
s
 
f
o
r
 
a
c
t
i
v
i
t
y
A
p
p
e
n
d
i
x
 
T
a
b
l
e
 
A
3
:
 
N
e
g
a
t
i
v
e
 
N
o
m
i
n
a
l
 
I
n
t
e
r
e
s
t
 
R
a
t
e
s
 
a
n
d
 
O
t
h
e
r
 
B
a
n
k
 
 
A
c
t
i
v
i
t
y
Slide Note
Embed
Share

Negative nominal interest rates, implemented following the financial crisis, have had a limited effect on bank performance globally. While low rates reduce profitability, banks have shown resilience through adjustments in funding allocations and non-interest income sources. Studies suggest that responses at the bank level have mitigated adverse impacts on profitability and lending. However, challenges remain in assessing the exact influence of negative rates on bank performance due to underlying economic fundamentals. Cross-country evidence indicates that banks generally resist charging negative rates on deposits, which disrupts monetary transmission mechanisms.

  • Negative rates
  • Bank performance
  • Financial crisis
  • Interest rates
  • Monetary policy

Uploaded on Oct 06, 2024 | 0 Views


Download Presentation

Please find below an Image/Link to download the presentation.

The content on the website is provided AS IS for your information and personal use only. It may not be sold, licensed, or shared on other websites without obtaining consent from the author. Download presentation by click this link. If you encounter any issues during the download, it is possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Why Have Negative Nominal Interest Rates Had Such a Small Effect on Bank Performance? Cross Country Evidence Jose A. Lopez, Andrew K. Rose, and Mark M. Spiegel* Bank for International Settlements July 6, 2018 *Comments are my own and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors or the FRBSF

  2. Low interest rates concern for banks Following financial crisis, rates reduced towards zero lower bound (ZLB) Potential obstacle to bank profitability Nominal deposit rates could not be reduced below zero without eroding banks customer base. Low interest rates reduce bank profitability [Jobst and Lin (2016)]. Concern confirmed empirically Borio, et al (2017) bank profitability reduced at low rates of interest Borio and Gambacorta (2017) bank lending less responsive to policy rates around ZLB, weakening transmission mechanism

  3. Even worse at negative rates Adjustments in deposit rates likely to hit a hard stop at the zero bound. Banks generally unwilling to charge negative nominal interest rates on deposits, especially for smaller customers Eggertson, et al (2017): Negative rates disrupt monetary transmission Evidence from aggregate data from five countries and the euro area as well as bank-level data from Sweden. Rostagno, et al (2016): movements into negative rates may induce lending by increasing cost of hoarding cash

  4. Many individual currency studies of negtive rates Bank-level studies Most conclude that responses at bank level mitigated adverse effect of negative rates on bank profitability and lending Increasing non-interest income (such as increased fees) Adjust funding allocations to rely less on deposits Adjustments depend on both bank business model and size, as both influence reliance on deposit funding However, move to negative rates likely reflects fundamentals Leaves it difficult to identify changes in bank profitability solely from negative rates.

  5. Relevant literature Studies under low positive rates Borio, et al (2017), Borio and Gambacorta (2017), Delis and Kouretas (2011), Bikker and Vervliet (2017) Economies under negative nominal interest rates Bech and Malkhozov (2016): 4 CBs in Europe since 2014 Negative rates similar to low positive rates Turk (2016): Danish and Swedish bank margins roughly stable across the zero threshold

  6. Micro data negative rate studies for individual currencies Heider, et al (2017): 46 eurozone banks 2013-2015 Negative rates in euro area induced deposit-dependent banks to cut lending, and reallocate loans towards more risky firms. Nucera, et al (2017): 111 eurozone banks Negative rates induced smaller banks to increase riskiness Basten and Mariathasan (2018): 68 Swiss banks Banks with higher excess reserves raised fees and interest income to compensate for negative liability margins Demiralp, et al (2017): 205 euro area banks HD banks extend more loans under negative rates than LD

  7. Multi-currency panel allows for global shocks Different economies move to negative rates at different times Include fixed time effects to control for global conditions Global shocks particularly relevant over sample period [Rey (2015)] Some countries in sample never experience negative rates Can be viewed as a difference-in-difference study Compare banks in economies that experienced negative rates, before and after policy rates turned negative Local conditions also likely affect both bank profitability and monetary policy Respond by instrumenting proxies for local conditions

  8. First study pooling European and Japanese banks under negative rates Annual income statements for 5,113 banks from 2010-2016 14 different currencies, one of which is the 19 country euro Countries go negative at different times for different reasons Example: Movements into negative rates different in floating and pegged exchange rate countries Latter respond more to pressures that might undermine the peg. Sample also includes large number of banks Allows analysis of banks most exposed to negative interest rates Split data into sub-samples by: a) bank size, and b) reliance on deposits.

  9. Results: Bank profitability unaffected by negative nominal interest rates No substantive effect on net income from negative rates. ssssNotable because sample includes relatively large share of small and high-deposit banks Both expected to be more exposed to negative rate losses Do find statistically significant losses in net interest income Statistically significant losses both on lending income and other interest income Mitigated by reductions in interest expenses, but not sufficiently Notably, banks do not substantially reduce deposit expenses Heterogeneity: Large banks do achieve reduction in deposit expenses, small banks don t

  10. Losses on net interest income made up on non- interest income Significant gains in net non-interest income Increases in fees Increases in other non-interest income (capital gains, gains on securities, insurance) Differences by bank type Large banks also reduce other interest expenses more than their smaller counterparts. Low-deposit (LD) banks do better under negative interest rates than high-deposit (HD) counterparts LD banks actually suffer bigger reductions in net interest income, but also achieve larger increases in net non-interest income

  11. Data Fitch Global Banking database Balance sheet and income statement variables for individual banks, 2010-2016 28 European countries and Japan Variety of monetary regimes, including monetary unions, exchange rate peggers, and inflation targeters Data begins 2 years before negative nominal interest rates Includes all negative nominal interest rate countries through 2016

  12. Difference from the existing literature Variety of countries with different monetary regimes Enter negative rates at different points in time, if at all. Five economies experienced negative nominal policy interest rates: Denmark, EMU, Japan, Sweden, and Switzerland Denmark first into negative rates July 2012 Swiss interest rates most negative (on sight deposit rates at -0.75%) Similar countries that did not go negative Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Hungary, and the UK Allows time fixed effects to account for global conditions More generally, difference-in-differences strategy, since not all experienced negative rates, and none for the entire sample.

  13. Data set is large Over 5,100 banks and more than 30,00 observations Allows examination of effects of negative rates on banks that differ by size and deposit-reliance Identify large as assets exceed $10 billion (1/8 of sample) Define HD as deposits exceeded 75% of funding (4/5 of sample) Complications Multiple accounting methods Generally choose unconsolidated observations Japanese banks report in first quarter Truncate outliers at 1% and 99%

  14. Losses on net interest income made up on non- interest income Significant gains in net non-interest income Increases in fees Increases in other non-interest income (capital gains, gains on securities, insurance) Differences by bank type Large banks also reduce other interest expenses more than their smaller counterparts. Low-deposit (LD) banks do better under negative interest rates than high-deposit (HD) counterparts LD banks actually suffer bigger reductions in net interest income, but also achieve larger increases in net non-interest income

  15. Little overall difference in profitability across ZLB Descriptive Statistics

  16. No apparent differences in raw data Figure 1: Bank profitability under positive and negative policy rates

  17. Base specification Conventional least-squares panel specification: Yijt= NEGIjt + { i} + { t} + ijt (1) where: Yijt is dependent variable for bank i in economy j for year t NEGIjt is 1 if country j had a negative nominal policy interest rate during year t, and 0 otherwise (nominal rates>1 are dropped) { } and { } are comprehensive sets of bank- and time-specific fixed effects represents a residual, assumed to be well-behaved

  18. Base specification (2) Coefficient of interest is Average effect of negative nominal interest rates Use robust standard errors, clustered by bank. Consider number of measures of bank performance Calculated as ratios of total assets Drop outliers, observations outside (1,99) percentiles Confirm results insensitive to the use of earning assets instead of total Exclude values of net income (to total assets) greater than 20% in absolute value

  19. Base specification results Negative Nominal Interest Rates and Bank Profitability

  20. Base results indicate small negative rate impact Economically small but positive and statistically insignificant effect on bank net income, compared with low positive rates Masks large movements in income components Net interest income falls significantly by around 5.4 bp Almost precisely offset by gains in net non-interest income of 5.2 bp. Offsetting results suggest banks are reluctant to charge their depositors negative rates Results in losses from interest income Compensate for losses with gains from non-interest income

  21. Results robust to variety of perturbations Sensitivity Analysis

  22. Decomposition of net interest income Negative Nominal Interest Rates and Bank Interest Income and Expenses

  23. Interest expense cuts less than revenue losses Both gross interest income and expense show economically significant and statistically significant declines Decline in expenses is smaller Decline in gross interest income largest for loan income Other interest income decline also significant Customer deposits insignificant Matches conventional wisdom Banks suffer interest losses but can t pass fully on to depositors Hence, bank net interest income declines

  24. Differences across banks Large banks seem more nimble than smaller banks Suffer smaller and insignificant declines in gross interest income Also cut expenses further, avoiding losses on net income LD banks suffer significantly greater losses in gross interest income, especially income from loans To offset losses, LD and HD banks lower interest expenses However, LD banks lower other interest expenses more More reliant on other, market-based funding sources Differences in deposit expenses much smaller

  25. Decomposition of non-interest income Negative Nominal Interest Rates and Bank Non-Interest Income and Expenses

  26. Interest expense cuts less than revenue losses Increase in net non-interest income stems from an increase in gross income, rather than a decline in expenses Two sources increasing gross income, both significant: Increase in net fees Improvements in other types of non-interest income, such as capital gains and gains on securities and insurance But change in most non-interest expenses insignificant Exception is other non-interest expenses, including capital gains on securities and interest expenses, which increase

  27. Differences across banks Few substantive differences between large and small banks Relatively large discrepancies across HD and LD banks Modest differences in point estimates for non-interest expenses Increase in gross non-interest income for LD banks about 10 times size of that enjoyed by HD banks Most from increases in non-fee income, which may reflect gains on securities May be associated with unanticipated movements into negative rates Benign impact of negative rates might in part reflect immediate capital gains on bond holdings for LD banks However, remaining under negative rates may not be painless Medium-tern impacts of negative rates may differ

  28. Differences across monetary regimes Data includes three different types of monetary regimes Large number members of EMU, (3 Baltic countries joined) Largest negative rate monetary regime Floating exchange rates Japan, Sweden and Switzerland (but not Czech Republic, Hungary or the UK) experienced negative nominal interest rates. Fixed exchange rates Bulgaria and Denmark (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania prior to EMU entry) Only Denmark experienced negative interest rates. Analysis implicitly exploits this panel variation Next, reexamine results by monetary regime

  29. Results for different monetary regimes Table 4: Negative Nominal Interest Rates Effects Across Economies

  30. Results indicate importance of panel approch Results for Japan and Germany erroneously negative Unable to control for time fixed effects; interpret with caution Demonstrates advantage of cross-country panel Literature often uses banks from single monetary regime Other samples more credible Countries with exchange rates pegged to the Euro European countries that maintained flexible exchange rates Flexers plus Eurozone All economies with flexible exchange rates

  31. Much heterogeneity across monetary regime panels None of the five panel estimates indicate significant effect of negative nominal interest rates on bank profitability Stark contrast with national results indicating significant decline in bank profits in both Japan and Germany Decomposition of sub-panels consistent with full sample Observed significant effect on net interest income always negative Significant coefficients for net non-interest income positive Result that negative rates only have a small overall effect appears driven by floating exchange rate economies

  32. Conclusion (1) Examine banks under negative nominal interest rates First study under negative rates for different monetary regimes Panel allows conditioning for global shocks, and dis-aggregating by both size and dependence on deposit-funding Find little overall impact on bank profitability, compared with low positive rates Components of income respond significantly Decline in net interest income Largely offset by increases in non-interest income Results driven by countries with floating exchange rates, and small or LD banks

  33. Conclusion (2) Overall, results suggest banks fare relatively well under negative nominal rates, compared to low positive Considerable heterogeneity raises caution in concluding that monetary transmission mechanism unchanged Particularly since positive returns in other non-interest income may be unsustainable over medium term Capital gains from negative interest rate surprises unlikely to persist

  34. Results for activity Appendix Table A3: Negative Nominal Interest Rates and Other Bank Activity

More Related Content

giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#giItT1WQy@!-/#